Stability–instability paradox
The stability–instability paradox is an international relations theory regarding the effect of nuclear weapons and mutually assured destruction. It states that when two countries each have nuclear weapons, the probability of a direct war between them greatly decreases, but the probability of minor or indirect conflicts between them increases.[1][2][3] This occurs because rational actors want to avoid nuclear wars, and thus they neither start major conflicts nor allow minor conflicts to escalate into major conflicts—thus making it safe to engage in minor conflicts. For instance, during the Cold War the United States and the Soviet Union never engaged each other in warfare, but fought proxy wars in Korea, Vietnam, Angola, the Middle East, Nicaragua and Afghanistan and spent substantial amounts of money and manpower on gaining relative influence over the third world.[4] A study published in the Journal of Conflict Resolution in 2009 quantitatively evaluated the nuclear peace hypothesis, and found support for the existence of the stability–instability paradox. The study determined that while nuclear weapons promote strategic stability, and prevent large scale wars, they simultaneously allow for more lower intensity conflicts. When one state has nuclear weapons, but their opponent does not, there is a greater chance of war. In contrast, when there is mutual nuclear weapon ownership with both states possessing nuclear weapons, the odds of war drop precipitously.[5]
This effect can be seen in the India–Pakistan relationship and to some degree in Russia–NATO relations.
Mechanism
The stability–instability paradox
posits that both parties to a conflict will rationally view strategic conflict and the attendant risk of a strategic nuclear exchange as untenable, and will thus avoid any escalation of sub-strategic conflicts to the strategic level. This effective “cap” on sub-strategic militarized conflict escalation emboldens states to engage in such conflict with the confidence that it would not spiral out of control and threaten their strategic interests. The causal force of this theory of increased sub-strategic conflict is the mutual recognition of the untenability of conflict at the level of strategic interests—a product of MAD [Mutually Assured Destruction]. With strategic interests forming the “red line” neither side would dare to cross, both sides are free to pursue sub-strategic political objectives through militarized conflict without the fear that the terms of such conflict will escalate beyond their control and jeopardize their strategic interests. Effectively, with the risk of uncontrolled escalation removed, the net costs to engage in conflict are reduced.[6]
Assumptions
One of the major assumptions in the concept of mutually assured destruction and the stability-instability phenomenon as its consequence is that all actors are rational and that this rationality implies an avoidance of complete destruction. Particularly the second part of the assumption might not necessarily be given in real-world politics. When imagining a theocratic nation whose leaders believe in the existence of an afterlife which they assume to be sufficiently better than our current life, it becomes rational for them to do everything in their power to facilitate a swift transition for as many people as possible into that afterlife. This connection between certain religious beliefs and politics of weapons of mass destruction has been pointed out by some atheists in order to point out perceived dangers of theocratic societies.[7]
See also
- Nuclear peace
- Minimal deterrence
- Deterrence theory
References
- ↑ Snyder, Glenn Herald (1965) (in en). The Balance of Power and the Balance of Terror. https://books.google.com/books?id=io4AcgAACAAJ.
- ↑ Jervis, Robert (1979). "Why Nuclear Superiority Doesn't Matter". Political Science Quarterly 94 (4): 617–633. doi:10.2307/2149629. ISSN 0032-3195. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2149629.
- ↑ Jervis, Robert (1989) (in en). The Meaning of the Nuclear Revolution: Statecraft and the Prospect of Armageddon. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-9565-6. https://books.google.com/books?id=WDeZHrS9r2EC.
- ↑ Krepon, Michael. "The Stability-Instability Paradox, Misperception, and Escalation Control in South Asia". The Henry Stimson Center. Archived from the original on 12 August 2017. https://web.archive.org/web/20170812115507/https://www.stimson.org/sites/default/files/file-attachments/stability-instability-paradox-south-asia.pdf. Retrieved 12 August 2017.
- ↑ Rauchhaus, Robert (2009). "Evaluating the Nuclear Peace Hypothesis - A Quantitative Approach". Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (2): 258–277. doi:10.1177/0022002708330387.
- ↑ Christopher J. Watterson 2017, 'Competing interpretations of the stability–instability paradox: the case of the Kargil War', The Nonproliferation Review, 24(1-2), 86, https://doi.org/10.1080/10736700.2017.1366623
- ↑ Harris, Sam (2005). The end of faith : Religion, terror, and the future of reason. W. W. Norton & Company. ISBN 9780393066722. https://archive.org/details/endoffaithreligi00harr.
Original source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Stability–instability paradox.
Read more |