Averch–Johnson effect

From HandWiki
Revision as of 19:25, 6 February 2024 by Sherlock (talk | contribs) (correction)
(diff) ← Older revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)

The Averch–Johnson effect is the tendency of regulated companies to engage in excessive amounts of capital accumulation in order to expand the volume of their profits. If companies' profits to capital ratio is regulated at a certain percentage then there is a strong incentive for companies to over-invest in order to increase profits overall. This investment goes beyond any optimal efficiency point for capital that the company may have calculated as higher profit is almost always desired over and above efficiency.[1] Excessive capital accumulation under rate-of-return regulation is informally known as gold plating.[2]

But the so-called Averch-Johnson effect of overcapitalization does not as a general case involve "gold-plating".[3]

Mathematical derivation

Suppose that a regulated firm wishes to maximize its profit:[math]\displaystyle{ \pi = R(K,L) - wL - rK }[/math]where [math]\displaystyle{ R(K,L) }[/math] is the revenue function, [math]\displaystyle{ K }[/math] is the firm's capital stock, [math]\displaystyle{ L }[/math] is the firm's labor stock, [math]\displaystyle{ w }[/math] is the wage rate, and [math]\displaystyle{ r }[/math] is the cost of capital. The firm's profit is constrained such that:[math]\displaystyle{ \sigma = {R-wL\over{K}} }[/math]where [math]\displaystyle{ \sigma }[/math] is the allowable rate of return. Assume that [math]\displaystyle{ \sigma \gt r }[/math]. We may then form a functional to find the firm's optimal action:[math]\displaystyle{ J = R(K,L)-wL-rK - \lambda[R(K,L)-wL-\sigma K] }[/math]where [math]\displaystyle{ \lambda }[/math] is the Lagrange multiplier (also known as the shadow price). The derivatives of this functional are:[math]\displaystyle{ \begin{aligned} {\partial J\over{\partial K}} &= (1-\lambda)R_{K} - r + \lambda \sigma \\ {\partial J\over{\partial L}} &= (1-\lambda)R_{L} - (1-\lambda)w \end{aligned} }[/math]Taken together, this implies that:[math]\displaystyle{ R_{K} = {r-\lambda \sigma\over{1-\lambda}}, \quad R_{L} = w }[/math]The ratio of the marginal product of capital and the marginal product of labor is:[math]\displaystyle{ {R_{K}\over{R_{L}}} = {r-\alpha\over{w}}, \quad \alpha = {\lambda\over{1-\lambda}}(\sigma - r) }[/math]Since this new cost of capital is perceived to be less than the market cost of capital, the firm will tend to overinvest in capital.[4]

See also

References

  1. Averch, Harvey; Johnson, Leland L. (1962). "Behavior of the Firm Under Regulatory Constraint". American Economic Review 52 (5): 1052–1069. 
  2. West, Michael (31 January 2013). "'Gold plating' rife, assets in for a hiding". The Age. http://www.theage.com.au/business/gold-plating-rife-assets-in-for-a-hiding-20130131-2dmjg.html. 
  3. Johnson, L.L. (1973). "Behavior of the Firm Under Regulatory Constraint: A Reassessment". American Economic Review 63 (2). https://www.jstor.org/stable/1817057. 
  4. Viscusi, W. Kip; Harrington, Jr., Joseph E.; Vernon, John M. (2005). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust (4th ed.). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. pp. 433–436. ISBN 9780262220750. https://mitpress.mit.edu/books/economics-regulation-and-antitrust-fourth-edition. 

Further reading

External links