Computational social choice

From HandWiki

Computational social choice is a field at the intersection of social choice theory, theoretical computer science, and the analysis of multi-agent systems.[1] It consists of the analysis of problems arising from the aggregation of preferences of a group of agents from a computational perspective. In particular, computational social choice is concerned with the efficient computation of outcomes of voting rules, with the computational complexity of various forms of manipulation, and issues arising from the problem of representing and eliciting preferences in combinatorial settings.

Winner determination

The usefulness of a particular voting system can be severely limited if it takes a very long time to calculate the winner of an election. Therefore, it is important to design fast algorithms that can evaluate a voting rule when given ballots as input. As is common in computational complexity theory, an algorithm is thought to be efficient if it takes polynomial time. Many popular voting rules can be evaluated in polynomial time in a straightforward way (i.e., counting), such as the Borda count, approval voting, or the plurality rule. For rules such as the Schulze method or ranked pairs, more sophisticated algorithms can be used to show polynomial runtime.[2][3] Certain voting systems, however, are computationally difficult to evaluate.[4] In particular, winner determination for the Kemeny-Young method, Dodgson's method, and Young's method are all NP-hard problems.[4][5][6][7] This has led to the development of approximation algorithms and fixed-parameter tractable algorithms to improve the theoretical calculation of such problems.[8][9][10]

Hardness of manipulation

By the Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorem, all non-trivial voting rules can be manipulated in the sense that voters can sometimes achieve a better outcome by misrepresenting their preferences, that is, they submit a non-truthful ballot to the voting system. Social choice theorists have long considered ways to circumvent this issue, such as the proposition by Bartholdi, Tovey, and Trick in 1989 based on computational complexity theory.[11] They considered the second-order Copeland rule (which can be evaluated in polynomial time), and proved that it is NP-complete for a voter to decide, given knowledge of how everyone else has voted, whether it is possible to manipulate in such a way as to make some favored candidate the winner. The same property holds for single transferable vote.[12]

Hence, assuming the widely believed hypothesis that P ≠ NP, there are instances where polynomial time is not enough to establish whether a beneficial manipulation is possible. Because of this, the voting rules that come with an NP-hard manipulation problem are "resistant" to manipulation. One should note that these results only concern the worst-case: it might well be possible that a manipulation problem is usually easy to solve, and only requires superpolynomial time on very unusual inputs.[13]

Other topics

Tournament solutions

A tournament solution is a rule that assigns to every tournament a set of winners. Since a preference profile induces a tournament through its majority relation, every tournament solution can also be seen as a voting rule which only uses information about the outcomes of pairwise majority contests.[14] Many tournament solutions have been proposed,[15] and computational social choice theorists have studied the complexity of the associated winner determination problems.[16][1]

Preference restrictions

Restricted preference domains, such as single-peaked or single-crossing preferences, are an important area of study in social choice theory, since preferences from these domains avoid the Condorcet paradox and thus can circumvent impossibility results like Arrow's theorem and the Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorem.[17][18][19][20] From a computational perspective, such domain restrictions are useful to speed up winner determination problems, both computationally hard single-winner and multi-winner rules can be computed in polynomial time when preferences are structured appropriately.[21][22][23][24] On the other hand, manipulation problem also tend to be easy on these domains, so complexity shields against manipulation are less effective.[22][25] Another computational problem associated with preference restrictions is that of recognizing when a given preference profile belongs to some restricted domain. This task is polynomial time solvable in many cases, including for single-peaked and single-crossing preferences, but can be hard for more general classes.[26][27][28]

Multiwinner elections

While most traditional voting rules focus on selecting a single winner, many situations require selecting multiple winners. This is the case when a fixed-size parliament or a committee is to be elected, though multiwinner voting rules can also be used to select a set of recommendations or facilities or a shared bundle of items. Work in computational social choice has focused on defining such voting rules, understanding their properties, and studying the complexity of the associated winner determination problems. See multiwinner voting.

See also

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 Brandt, Felix; Conitzer, Vincent; Endriss, Ulle; Lang, Jérôme; Procaccia, Ariel D. (2016-04-25). Handbook of Computational Social Choice. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9781107060432. https://books.google.com/books?id=nMHgCwAAQBAJ. 
  2. Schulze, Markus (2010-07-11). "A new monotonic, clone-independent, reversal symmetric, and condorcet-consistent single-winner election method". Social Choice and Welfare 36 (2): 267–303. doi:10.1007/s00355-010-0475-4. 
  3. Brill, Markus; Fischer, Felix (2012-01-01). "The Price of Neutrality for the Ranked Pairs Method". Proceedings of the Twenty-Sixth AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence. AAAI'12: 1299–1305. http://dl.acm.org/citation.cfm?id=2900728.2900912. 
  4. 4.0 4.1 Bartholdi III, J.; Tovey, C. A.; Trick, M. A. (1989-04-01). "Voting schemes for which it can be difficult to tell who won the election". Social Choice and Welfare 6 (2): 157–165. doi:10.1007/BF00303169. 
  5. Hemaspaandra, Edith; Spakowski, Holger; Vogel, Jörg (2005-12-16). "The complexity of Kemeny elections". Theoretical Computer Science 349 (3): 382–391. doi:10.1016/j.tcs.2005.08.031. 
  6. Hemaspaandra, Edith; Hemaspaandra, Lane A.; Rothe, Jörg (1997). "Exact Analysis of Dodgson Elections: Lewis Carroll's 1876 Voting System is Complete for Parallel Access to NP". J. ACM 44 (6): 806–825. doi:10.1145/268999.269002. 
  7. Rothe, Jörg; Spakowski, Holger; Vogel, Jörg (2003-06-06). "Exact Complexity of the Winner Problem for Young Elections". Theory of Computing Systems 36 (4): 375–386. doi:10.1007/s00224-002-1093-z. 
  8. Caragiannis, Ioannis; Covey, Jason A.; Feldman, Michal; Homan, Christopher M.; Kaklamanis, Christos; Karanikolas, Nikos; Procaccia, Ariel D.; Rosenschein, Jeffrey S. (2012-08-01). "On the approximability of Dodgson and Young elections". Artificial Intelligence 187: 31–51. doi:10.1016/j.artint.2012.04.004. 
  9. Ailon, Nir; Charikar, Moses; Newman, Alantha (2008-11-01). "Aggregating Inconsistent Information: Ranking and Clustering". J. ACM 55 (5): 23:1–23:27. doi:10.1145/1411509.1411513. 
  10. Betzler, Nadja; Fellows, Michael R.; Guo, Jiong; Niedermeier, Rolf; Rosamond, Frances A. (2008-06-23). "Fixed-Parameter Algorithms for Kemeny Scores". in Fleischer, Rudolf. Algorithmic Aspects in Information and Management. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 5034. Springer Berlin Heidelberg. pp. 60–71. doi:10.1007/978-3-540-68880-8_8. ISBN 9783540688655. 
  11. Bartholdi, J. J.; Tovey, C. A.; Trick, M. A. (1989). "The computational difficulty of manipulating an election". Social Choice and Welfare 6 (3): 227–241. doi:10.1007/BF00295861. 
  12. Bartholdi, John J.; Orlin, James B. (1991). "Single transferable vote resists strategic voting". Social Choice and Welfare 8 (4): 341–354. doi:10.1007/BF00183045. 
  13. Faliszewski, Piotr; Procaccia, Ariel D. (2010-09-23). "AI's War on Manipulation: Are We Winning?". AI Magazine 31 (4): 53–64. doi:10.1609/aimag.v31i4.2314. http://www.aaai.org/ojs/index.php/aimagazine/article/view/2314. 
  14. Fishburn, P. (1977-11-01). "Condorcet Social Choice Functions". SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics 33 (3): 469–489. doi:10.1137/0133030. 
  15. Laslier, Jean-François (1997). Tournament Solutions and Majority Voting. Springer Verlag. 
  16. Moon, John W. (1968-01-01). Topics on tournaments. Holt, Rinehart and Winston. https://books.google.com/books?id=P9Q-AAAAIAAJ. 
  17. Black, Duncan (1948-01-01). "On the Rationale of Group Decision-making". Journal of Political Economy 56 (1): 23–34. doi:10.1086/256633. 
  18. Rothstein, P. (1990-12-01). "Order restricted preferences and majority rule". Social Choice and Welfare 7 (4): 331–342. doi:10.1007/BF01376281. 
  19. Arrow, Kenneth J. (2012-06-26). Social Choice and Individual Values. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0300186987. https://books.google.com/books?id=y_rkX6QWOYMC. 
  20. Sen, Amartya; Pattanaik, Prasanta K (1969-08-01). "Necessary and sufficient conditions for rational choice under majority decision". Journal of Economic Theory 1 (2): 178–202. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(69)90020-9. 
  21. Elkind, Edith; Lackner, Martin; Peters, Dominik (2016-07-01). "Preference Restrictions in Computational Social Choice: Recent Progress". Proceedings of the 25th International Conference on Artificial Intelligence. IJCAI'16: 4062–4065. http://www.ijcai.org/Proceedings/16/Papers/601.pdf. 
  22. 22.0 22.1 Brandt, Felix; Brill, Markus; Hemaspaandra, Edith; Hemaspaandra, Lane (2015-01-01). "Bypassing Combinatorial Protections: Polynomial-Time Algorithms for Single-Peaked Electorates". Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research 53: 439–496. doi:10.1613/jair.4647. 
  23. N., Betzler; A., Slinko; J., Uhlmann (2013). "On the Computation of Fully Proportional Representation". Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research 47 (2013): 475–519. doi:10.1613/jair.3896. Bibcode2014arXiv1402.0580B. http://www.jair.org/papers/paper3896.html. 
  24. Skowron, Piotr; Yu, Lan; Faliszewski, Piotr; Elkind, Edith (2015-03-02). "The complexity of fully proportional representation for single-crossing electorates". Theoretical Computer Science 569: 43–57. doi:10.1016/j.tcs.2014.12.012. 
  25. Faliszewski, Piotr; Hemaspaandra, Edith; Hemaspaandra, Lane A.; Rothe, Jörg (2011-02-01). "The shield that never was: Societies with single-peaked preferences are more open to manipulation and control". Information and Computation 209 (2): 89–107. doi:10.1016/j.ic.2010.09.001. 
  26. Peters, Dominik (2016-02-25). "Recognising Multidimensional Euclidean Preferences". arXiv:1602.08109 [cs.GT].
  27. Doignon, J. P.; Falmagne, J. C. (1994-03-01). "A Polynomial Time Algorithm for Unidimensional Unfolding Representations". Journal of Algorithms 16 (2): 218–233. doi:10.1006/jagm.1994.1010. https://dipot.ulb.ac.be/dspace/bitstream/2013/310087/3/1994_Doignon_Falmagne.pdf. 
  28. Escoffier, Bruno; Lang, Jérôme; Öztürk, Meltem (2008-01-01). "Single-peaked Consistency and Its Complexity". Proceedings of the 2008 Conference on ECAI 2008: 18th European Conference on Artificial Intelligence: 366–370. ISBN 9781586038915. http://dl.acm.org/citation.cfm?id=1567281.1567363. 

External links

  • The COMSOC website, offering a collection of materials related to computational social choice, such as academic workshops, PhD theses, and a mailing list.