Finance:AK model

From HandWiki

The AK model of economic growth is an endogenous growth model used in the theory of economic growth, a subfield of modern macroeconomics. In the 1980s it became progressively clearer that the standard neoclassical exogenous growth models were theoretically unsatisfactory as tools to explore long run growth, as these models predicted economies without technological change and thus they would eventually converge to a steady state, with zero per capita growth. A fundamental reason for this is the diminishing return of capital; the key property of AK endogenous-growth model is the absence of diminishing returns to capital. In lieu of the diminishing returns of capital implied by the usual parameterizations of a Cobb–Douglas production function, the AK model uses a linear model where output is a linear function of capital. Its appearance in most textbooks is to introduce endogenous growth theory.[1]

Graphical representation of the model

The AK model production function is a special case of a Cobb–Douglas function with constant returns to scale.

[math]\displaystyle{ Y=AK^aL^{1-a}\, }[/math]

This equation shows a Cobb–Douglas function where Y represents the total production in an economy. A represents total factor productivity, K is capital, L is labor, and the parameter [math]\displaystyle{ a }[/math] measures the output elasticity of capital. For the special case in which [math]\displaystyle{ a = 1 }[/math], the production function becomes linear in capital and does not have the property of decreasing returns to scale in the capital stock, which would prevail for any other value of the capital intensity between 0 and 1.

[math]\displaystyle{ n }[/math] = population growth rate
[math]\displaystyle{ \delta\ }[/math] = depreciation
[math]\displaystyle{ k }[/math] = capital per worker
[math]\displaystyle{ y }[/math] = output/income per worker
[math]\displaystyle{ L }[/math] = labor force
[math]\displaystyle{ s }[/math] = saving rate

In an alternative form [math]\displaystyle{ Y=AK }[/math], [math]\displaystyle{ K }[/math] embodies both physical capital and human capital.

[math]\displaystyle{ Y=AK\, }[/math]

In the above equation A is the level of technology which is positive constant and K represents volume of capital. Hence, output per capita is:

[math]\displaystyle{ \frac{Y}{L}=A \cdot \frac{K}{L} }[/math] i.e. [math]\displaystyle{ y = Ak }[/math]

The model implicitly assumes that the average product of capital is equal to marginal product of capital which is equivalent to:

[math]\displaystyle{ A \gt 0 }[/math]

The model again assumes that labor force is growing at a constant rate ‘n’ and there is no depreciation of capital. (δ = 0 ) In this case, the basic differential equation of neo-classical growth model would be:

[math]\displaystyle{ k(t) = s \cdot f(k) - nk }[/math]

Hence, [math]\displaystyle{ \frac{k(t)}{k} = s \cdot \frac{f(k)}{k} - n }[/math]

But in the model [math]\displaystyle{ \frac{f(k)}{k} = A }[/math]

Thus, [math]\displaystyle{ \frac{k(t)}{k} = s \cdot A - n }[/math]

The united approach to the model

To avoid the contradictions, Russian economist Vladimir Pokrovskii proposed to write the production function in the united form

[math]\displaystyle{ Y = \begin{cases} \xi K, & \xi \gt 0 \\ Y_0 \frac{L}{L_0}\left(\frac {L_0}{L} \frac{P}{P_0}\right)^\alpha, & 0 \lt \alpha \lt 1 \end{cases} }[/math]

where [math]\displaystyle{ P }[/math] is a capital severce; [math]\displaystyle{ Y_0 }[/math], [math]\displaystyle{ L_0 }[/math] and [math]\displaystyle{ P_0 }[/math] correspond to output, labour and substitutive work in the base year. This form of the theory explains growth as a consequence of the dynamics of the production factors, without any arbitrary parameters, which makes it possible to reproduce historical rates of economic growth with considerable precision.[2][3][4]

See also

References

  1. Romer, Paul M. (1986). "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth". Journal of Political Economy 94 (5): 1002–1037. doi:10.1086/261420. 
  2. Pokrovski, V.N. (2003). Energy in the theory of production. Energy 28, 769-788.
  3. Pokrovski, V.N. (2007) Productive energy in the US economy, Energy 32 (5) 816-822.
  4. Pokrovskii, Vladimir (2021). "Social resources in the theory of economic growth". The Complex Systems (3): 32–43. https://thecomplexsystems.com/. 

Further reading