Philosophy:Law and economics
Part of a series on |
Economics |
---|
|
Law and economics, or economic analysis of law, is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law. The field emerged in the United States during the early 1960s, primarily from the work of scholars from the Chicago school of economics such as Aaron Director, George Stigler, and Ronald Coase. The field uses economics concepts to explain the effects of laws, to assess which legal rules are economically efficient, and to predict which legal rules will be promulgated.[1] There are two major branches of law and economics;[2] one based on the application of the methods and theories of neoclassical economics to the positive and normative analysis of the law, and a second branch which focuses on an institutional analysis of law and legal institutions, with a broader focus on economic, political, and social outcomes, and overlapping with analyses of the institutions of politics and governance.
History
Origin
The historical antecedents of law and economics can be traced back to the classical economists, who are credited with the foundations of modern economic thought. As early as the 18th century, Adam Smith discussed the economic effects of mercantilist legislation; later, David Ricardo opposed the British Corn Laws on the grounds that they hindered agricultural productivity; and Frédéric Bastiat, in his influential book The Law, examined the unintended consequences of legislation. However, to apply economics to analyze the law regulating nonmarket activities is relatively new. A European law & economics movement around 1900 did not have any lasting influence.[3]
Harold Luhnow, the head of the Volker Fund, not only financed F. A. Hayek in the U.S. starting in 1946, but he shortly thereafter financed Aaron Director's coming to the University of Chicago in order to set up there a new center for scholars in law and economics. The University was headed by Robert Maynard Hutchins, a close collaborator of Luhnow's in setting up the Chicago School, as it became commonly known. The university faculty then included a strong base of libertarian scholars, including Frank Knight, George Stigler, Henry Simons, Ronald Coase and Jacob Viner.[4] Soon, it would also have not just Hayek himself, but Director's brother-in-law and Stigler's friend Milton Friedman, and also Robert Fogel, Robert Lucas, Eugene Fama, Richard Posner, and Gary Becker.
Historians Robert van Horn and Philip Mirowski described the development of modern economic concepts in "The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics", a chapter of The Road from Mont Pelerin (2009); and historian Bruce Caldwell (a great admirer of von Hayek) filled in more details of the account in his chapter, "The Chicago School, Hayek, and Neoliberalism", in Building Chicago Economics (2011). The field began with Gary Becker's 1968 paper on crime (Becker also received a Nobel Prize). In 1972, Richard Posner, a law and economics scholar and the major advocate of the positive theory of efficiency, published the first edition of Economic Analysis of Law and founded The Journal of Legal Studies, both are regarded as important events. Gordon Tullock and Friedrich Hayek also wrote intensively in the area and influenced to spread of law and economics.
Founding
In 1958, Director founded The Journal of Law & Economics, which he co-edited with Nobel laureate Ronald Coase, and which helped to unite the fields of law and economics with far-reaching influence.[5] In 1960 and 1961, Ronald Coase and Guido Calabresi independently published two groundbreaking articles, "The Problem of Social Cost"[6] and "Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts".[7] This can be seen as the starting point for the modern school of law and economics.[8]
In 1962, Aaron Director helped to found the Committee on a Free Society. Director's appointment to the faculty of the University of Chicago Law School in 1946 began a half-century of intellectual productivity, although his reluctance about publishing left few writings behind.[9] He taught antitrust courses at the law school with Edward Levi, who eventually would serve as Dean of Chicago's Law School, President of the University of Chicago, and as U.S. Attorney General in the Ford administration. After retiring from the University of Chicago Law School in 1965, Director relocated to California and took a position at Stanford University's Hoover Institution. He died September 11, 2004, at his home in Los Altos Hills, California, ten days before his 103rd birthday.
Later development
In the early 1970s, Henry Manne (a former student of Coase) set out to build a center for law and economics at a major law school. He began at the University of Rochester, worked at the University of Miami, but was soon made unwelcome, moved to Emory University, and ended up at George Mason.[10] The last soon became a center for the education of judges—many long out of law school and never exposed to numbers and economics. Manne also attracted the support of the John M. Olin Foundation, whose support accelerated the movement. Today, Olin centers (or programs) for Law and Economics exist at many universities.
Chicago School notable figures
Modern forerunners of economic thought developed at the Chicago School include Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and Frédéric Bastiat.
Founders include:
- Aaron Director, University of Chicago[9][11]
- Ronald Coase, University of Chicago, 1991 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences[12]
- Richard Posner, University of Chicago[13][14]
- Guido Calabresi, Yale University.[15][16] Calabresi, judge for the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, wrote in depth on this subject; his book The Costs of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis (1970) has been cited as influential in its extensive treatment of the proper incentives and compensation required in accident situations.[17] Calabresi took a different approach in Ideals, Beliefs, Attitudes, and the Law (1985), where he argued, "who is the cheapest avoider of a cost, depends on the valuations put on acts, activities and beliefs by the whole of our law and not on some objective or scientific notion" (69).
- Henry Manne, George Mason University[15]
Other notable individuals include:
- Gary Becker, Nobel Memorial Prize–winning economist and a leader of the Chicago School of Economics[18]
- Frank Easterbrook, U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit judge
- Andrei Shleifer
- Robert Cooter
- Harold Demsetz
- Hans-Bernd Schäfer
- William Landes
- W. Kip Viscusi
- A. Mitchell Polinsky
- Michael Trebilcock
Positive and normative law and economics
Economic analysis of law is usually divided into two subfields: positive and normative.
Positive law and economics
'Positive law and economics' uses economic analysis to predict the effects of various legal rules. So, for example, a positive economic analysis of tort law would predict the effects of a strict liability rule as opposed to the effects of a negligence rule. Positive law and economics has also at times purported to explain the development of legal rules, for example the common law of torts, in terms of their economic efficiency.
Normative law and economics
Normative law and economics goes one step further and makes policy recommendations based on the economic consequences of various policies. The key concept for normative economic analysis is efficiency, in particular, allocative efficiency.
A common concept of efficiency used by law and economics scholars is Pareto efficiency. A legal rule is Pareto efficient if it could not be changed so as to make one person better off without making another person worse off. A weaker conception of efficiency is Kaldor–Hicks efficiency. A legal rule is Kaldor–Hicks efficient if it could be made Pareto efficient by some parties compensating others as to offset their loss.
Nonetheless, the possibility of a clear distinction between positive and normative analysis has been questioned by Guido Calabresi who, in his book on "The future of Law and Economics" (2016: 21-22), believes that there is an "actual - and unavoidable - existence of value judgments underlying much economic analysis"[19]
Uri Weiss proposed this alternative: "It is common in law and economics to search for the law that will lead to the optimal outcome, providing the maximum size 'pie,' and to think about maximizing happiness instead of minimizing pain. We prefer another approach: We do not try to identify games that will lead to the optimal result but to prevent games in which it is in the best interests of the players to come to an unjust result".[20]
Criminal law
In 1968, Gary Becker, who would later win the Nobel prize for economics, published Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.[21] This work relied on the economic concept of utility as the basic unit of analysis. In 1985, in An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law, Posner set out an alternative approach that relied instead on wealth as the basic unit of analysis.[22]
Relationship to other disciplines and approaches
As used by lawyers and legal scholars, the phrase "law and economics" refers to the application of microeconomic analysis to legal problems. Because of the overlap between legal systems and political systems, some of the issues in law and economics are also raised in political economy, constitutional economics and political science.
Approaches to the same issues from Marxist and critical theory/Frankfurt School perspectives usually do not identify themselves as "law and economics". For example, research by members of the critical legal studies movement and the sociology of law considers many of the same fundamental issues as does work labeled "law and economics", though from a vastly different perspective. The law and political economy movement also analyzes similar concepts using an entirely different approach.[23]
The one wing that represents a non-neoclassical approach to "law and economics" is the Continental (mainly German) tradition that sees the concept starting out of the governance and public policy (Staatswissenschaften) approach and the German Historical school of economics; this view is represented in the Elgar Companion to Law and Economics (2nd ed. 2005) and—though not exclusively—in the European Journal of Law and Economics. Here, consciously non-neoclassical approaches to economics are used for the analysis of legal (and administrative/governance) problems.
Law and economics is closely related to jurimetrics, the application of probability and statistics to legal questions.
Applications
- Affirmative action (Coate-Loury model)
- Antitrust law (Herfindahl–Hirschman Index)
- Calculus of negligence
- Congestion pricing
- Corporate governance[24][25][26]
- Cost–benefit analysis
- Criminal law[27]
- Mass surveillance in the United States[28]
- Surveillance
- Crime enforcement[29][30]
- Deregulation (Airlines, communications, energy, surface freight)
- Design of contracts (Contract theory)
- Discrimination
- Statistical discrimination (economics)
- Drug policy (Iron law of prohibition)
- Evidence[31][32]
- Evolution of the common law[33][34] (Evolutionary game theory[35])
- Financial regulation (Efficient market hypothesis)
- Fraud-on-the-market theory
- Governance of the commons[36]
- Institutional origins
- The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation
- Constitutional economics
- Legal origins theory
- Property rights[37][38]
- Intellectual property (Economics and patents)
- Natural monopoly regulation (Averch–Johnson effect)
- Peltzman effect
- Principal–agent problem
- Quarantine measures for public health[39][40]
- Prudent investor rule[41] (Modern portfolio theory)
- Rent control[42][43]
- Rent-seeking[44]
- Transaction costs (Coase theorem)
- Value of a statistical life[45][46]
- Voting systems (Social choice theory)
- Water law[47][48]
Influence
The economic analysis of law has been influential in the United States as well as elsewhere. Judicial opinions use economic analysis and the theories of law and economics with some regularity, in the US but also, increasingly, in Commonwealth countries and in Europe. The influence of law and economics has also been felt in legal education, with graduate programs in the subject being offered in a number of countries. The influence of law and economics in civil law countries may be gauged from the availability of textbooks of law and economics, in English as well as in other European languages (Schäfer and Ott 2004; Mackaay 2013).
Many law schools in North America, Europe, and Asia have faculty members with a graduate degree in economics. In addition, many professional economists now study and write on the relationship between economics and legal doctrines. Anthony Kronman, former dean of Yale Law School, has written that "the intellectual movement that has had the greatest influence on American academic law in the past quarter-century [of the 20th Century]" is law and economics.[49]
Criticisms
Despite its influence, the law and economics movement has been criticized from a number of directions. This is especially true of normative law and economics. Because most law and economics scholarship operates within a neoclassical framework, fundamental criticisms of neoclassical economics have been drawn from other, competing frameworks, though there are numerous internal critiques as well.[50] Yet other schools of economic thought have emerged and have been applied to the work of law and economics in, for example, the work of Edgardo Buscaglia and Robert Cooter in the book "Law and Economics of Development".[51]
Rational choice theory
Critics of the economic analysis of legal questions have argued that normative economic analysis does not capture the importance of human rights and concerns for distributive justice. Some of the heaviest criticisms of law and economics come from the critical legal studies movement, in particular Duncan Kennedy[52] and Mark Kelman. Jon D. Hanson, of Harvard Law School, argues that our legal, economic, political, and social systems are unduly influenced by an individualistic model of behavior based on preferences, instead of a model that incorporates cognitive biases and social norms.[53]
Pareto efficiency
Additional criticism has been directed toward the assumed benefits of law and policy designed to increase allocative efficiency when such assumptions are modeled on "first-best" (Pareto optimal) general-equilibrium conditions. Under the theory of the second best, for example, if the fulfillment of a subset of optimal conditions cannot be met under any circumstances, it is incorrect to conclude that the fulfillment of any subset of optimal conditions will necessarily result in an increase in allocative efficiency.[54]
Consequently, any expression of public policy whose purported purpose is an unambiguous increase in allocative efficiency (for example, consolidation of research and development costs through increased mergers and acquisitions resulting from a systematic relaxation of antitrust laws) is, according to critics, fundamentally incorrect, as there is no general reason to conclude that an increase in allocative efficiency is more likely than a decrease.
Essentially, the "first-best" neoclassical analysis fails to properly account for various kinds of general-equilibrium feedback relationships that result from intrinsic Pareto imperfections.[54]
Another critique comes from the fact that there is no unique optimal result. Warren Samuels in his 2007 book, The Legal-Economic Nexus, argues, "efficiency in the Pareto sense cannot dispositively be applied to the definition and assignment of rights themselves, because efficiency requires an antecedent determination of the rights (23–4)".
"Internal" analytical criticisms
Relatedly, legal scholarship also has criticized the movement for allowing its framing of models to dictate its results, for over-emphasizing or under-emphasizing specific incentives and costs, and for building models that do not degrade "gracefully" (and therefore have difficulty modeling reality).[55] In other words, the law and economics movement may not achieve "efficiency", even to the extent allocative efficiency is the goal of the law.[56]
Criminal methodology
Cullerne Bown has criticised Posner's approach on methodological grounds. He concludes that Posner's approach to evaluating policies in the criminal process is methodologically invalid and that "these failings in turn make the entirety of his conclusions on the criminal process unreliable".[57]
Responses to criticism
Law and economics has adapted to some of these criticisms and been developed in a variety of directions. One important trend has been the application of game theory to legal problems.[58] Other developments have been the incorporation of behavioral economics into economic analysis of law,[59] and the increasing use of statistical and econometrics techniques.[60] Within the legal academy, the term socio-economics has been applied to economic approaches that are self-consciously broader than the neoclassical tradition.
Property rights, which are analyzed using economic analysis, are seen as fundamental human rights by defenders of law and economics.[61]
See also
- Competition policy
- Contract theory
- Constitutionalism
- Constitutional economics
- Cost–benefit analysis
- Economic imperialism (economics)
- Economics
- Iron law of prohibition
- Islamic economical jurisprudence
- Jurimetrics
- Legal origins theory
- Legal theory
- Microeconomics
- New institutional economics
- Occupational licensing
- Political economy
- Property rights (economics)
- Public choice theory
References
- ↑ David Friedman (1987). "law and economics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, p. 144.
- ↑ Ronald Coase (1996). "Law and Economics and A.W. Brian Simpson," The Journal of Legal Studies, v. 25, p. 103-104.
- ↑ Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, p. 295–360; Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
- ↑ Hayek's journey: the mind of Friedrich Hayek by Alan Ebenstein, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003, pages 164–165. Retrieved November 10, 2022.
- ↑ Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, p. 295–360
- ↑ Coase, Ronald (1960). "The Problem of Social Cost". The Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1): 1–44. doi:10.1086/466560. https://www.law.uchicago.edu/files/file/coase-problem.pdf. Retrieved 2019-09-08. This issue was actually published in 1961.
- ↑ Calabresi, Guido (1961). "Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts". Yale Law Journal 70 (4): 499–553. doi:10.2307/794261. https://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=8833&context=ylj.
- ↑ Posner, Richard (1983). The Economics of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. p. 4. ISBN 978-0-674-23525-0. https://archive.org/details/economi_pos_1981_00_0099/page/4.
- ↑ 9.0 9.1 "Aaron Director, Founder of the field of Law and Economics". http://www-news.uchicago.edu/releases/04/040913.director.shtml.
- ↑ "Spotlight: Henry G. Manne ROBERT POOLE, Reason, May 1976. Retrieved October 7, 2022.
- ↑ "Aaron Director" (in en). 2014-06-20. https://mises.org/profile/aaron-director-0.
- ↑ "Ronald H. Coase" (in en-US). https://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Coase.html.
- ↑ "Swan Song of a Great Colossus: The Latest from Richard Posner" (in en-US). 2019-05-13. https://www.lawliberty.org/2019/05/13/swan-song-of-a-great-colossus-the-latest-from-richard-posner/.
- ↑ "Posner, Richard Allen". https://www.jewishvirtuallibrary.org/posner-richard-allen.
- ↑ 15.0 15.1 Gordon, Wendy J.; Marciano, Alain; Ramello, Giovanni B. (2019-08-01). "The future of law and economics and the legacy of Guido Calabresi" (in en). European Journal of Law and Economics 48 (1): 1–8. doi:10.1007/s10657-019-09626-5. ISSN 1572-9990.
- ↑ Stojanović, Aleksandar; Silvestri, Paolo (October 1, 2019). "The Road Not Taken – Reading Calabresi's "The Future of Law and Economics"". Global Jurist 19 (3). doi:10.1515/gj-2019-0040. https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/gj-2019-0040/html.
- ↑ Litan, Robert (1988). Liability: Perspectives and Policy. Brookings Institution Press. ISBN 978-0-8157-5271-4. https://archive.org/details/liabilityperspec0000unse.
- ↑ "The Fourth Generation in Chicago" (in en-US). 2014-11-16. http://www.economicprincipals.com/issues/2014.11.16/1664.html.
- ↑ Silvestri, Paolo (October 1, 2019). "On the (Methodological) Future of Law and Economics. The Uneasy Burden of Value Judgments and Normativity". Global Jurist 19 (3). doi:10.1515/gj-2019-0026. https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/gj-2019-0026/html.
- ↑ "The Regressive Effect of Legal Uncertainty" Uri Weiss, Journal of Dispute Resolution, 2019, page 152. Retrieved October 23, 2022.
- ↑ Becker, Gary (March 1, 1968), "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach", Journal of Political Economy 76 (2): 169, doi:10.1086/259394, http://www.nber.org/chapters/c3625.pdf
- ↑ Posner, Richard (October 1985), "An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law", Columbia Law Review 85 (6): 1193–1231, doi:10.2307/1122392, https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=2827&context=journal_articles
- ↑ "Toward a Manifesto" (in en-US). https://lpeproject.org/lpe-manifesto/.
- ↑ Hart, Oliver (1995). "Corporate Governance: Some Theory and Implications". The Economic Journal 105 (430): 678–689. doi:10.2307/2235027. ISSN 0013-0133.
- ↑ La Porta, Rafael; Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert (2000-01-01). "Investor protection and corporate governance". Journal of Financial Economics. Special Issue on International Corporate Governance 58 (1): 3–27. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00065-9. ISSN 0304-405X. https://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/1/29408126/1/w7428.pdf.
- ↑ Bebchuk, Lucian; Cohen, Alma; Ferrell, Allen (2009-02-01). "What Matters in Corporate Governance?" (in en). The Review of Financial Studies 22 (2): 783–827. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhn099. ISSN 0893-9454. https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/22/2/783/1596611.
- ↑ Brown, Darryl K. (2004). "Cost–Benefit Analysis in Criminal Law". California Law Review 92 (2): 323–372. doi:10.2307/3481427. ISSN 0008-1221. https://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1339&context=californialawreview.[yes|permanent dead link|dead link}}]
- ↑ Mueller, John; G, Stewart Mark (2014–2015). "Secret without Reason and Costly without Accomplishment: Questioning the National Security Agency's Metadata Program". I/S: A Journal of Law and Policy for the Information Society 10: 407. https://politicalscience.osu.edu/faculty/jmueller/NSAshane3.pdf.
- ↑ Becker, Gary S. (1968). "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach" (in en). Journal of Political Economy 76 (2): 169–217. doi:10.1086/259394. ISSN 0022-3808. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c3625.pdf.
- ↑ Levitt, Steven D (2004). "Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors that Explain the Decline and Six that Do Not" (in en). Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (1): 163–190. doi:10.1257/089533004773563485. ISSN 0895-3309.
- ↑ Posner, Richard A. (1999). "An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence". John M. Olin Law & Economics Working Paper No. 66 (University of Chicago Law School). https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1044&context=law_and_economics.
- ↑ Lempert, Richard (2001). "The Economic Analysis of Evidence Law: Common Sense on Stilts". Virginia Law Review 87 (8): 1619–1712. doi:10.2307/1073903. ISSN 0042-6601. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1073903.
- ↑ Terrebonne, R. Peter (1981). "A Strictly Evolutionary Model of Common Law". The Journal of Legal Studies 10 (2): 397–407. doi:10.1086/467688. ISSN 0047-2530.
- ↑ Gennaioli, Nicola; Shleifer, Andrei (2007). "The Evolution of Common Law". Journal of Political Economy 115 (1): 43–68. doi:10.1086/511996. ISSN 0022-3808.
- ↑ Friedman, Daniel (1998). "On economic applications of evolutionary game theory". Journal of Evolutionary Economics 8: 15–43. doi:10.1007/s001910050054. http://www.dklevine.com/archive/refs453.pdf.
- ↑ Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-40599-7.
- ↑ Demsetz, Harold (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights". The American Economic Review 57 (2): 347–359. ISSN 0002-8282.
- ↑ Alchian, Armen A.; Demsetz, Harold (1973). "The Property Right Paradigm". The Journal of Economic History 33 (1): 16–27. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076403. ISSN 0022-0507.
- ↑ Gostin, Lawrence (2006). "Public Health Strategies for Pandemic Influenza: Ethics and the Law". JAMA 295 (14): 1700–1704. doi:10.1001/jama.295.14.1700. PMID 16609092.
- ↑ Fidler, David P.; Gostin, Lawrence O.; Markel, Howard (2007). "Through the Quarantine Looking Glass: Drug-Resistant Tuberculosis and Public Health Governance, Law, and Ethics". The Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics 35 (4): 616–628. doi:10.1111/j.1748-720X.2007.00185.x. PMID 18076513. https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1370&context=facpub.
- ↑ "Modern Portfolio Theory" (in en). Cornell Law School. https://www.law.cornell.edu/wex/modern_portfolio_theory.
- ↑ Glaeser, Edward L.; Luttmer, Erzo F. P. (2003). "The Misallocation of Housing Under Rent Control" (in en). American Economic Review 93 (4): 1027–1046. doi:10.1257/000282803769206188. ISSN 0002-8282. http://www.nber.org/papers/w6220.pdf.
- ↑ Diamond, Rebecca; McQuade, Tim; Qian, Franklin (2019). "The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco" (in en). American Economic Review 109 (9): 3365–3394. doi:10.1257/aer.20181289. ISSN 0002-8282.
- ↑ Krueger, Anne O. (1974). "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society". The American Economic Review 64 (3): 291–303. ISSN 0002-8282.
- ↑ Viscusi, W. Kip (1993). "The Value of Risks to Life and Health". Journal of Economic Literature 31 (4): 1912–1946. ISSN 0022-0515.
- ↑ Viscusi, W. Kip; Aldy, Joseph E. (2003-08-01). "The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World" (in en). Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27 (1): 5–76. doi:10.1023/A:1025598106257. ISSN 1573-0476.
- ↑ Burness, H. Stuart; Quirk, James P. (1980). "Water Law, Water Transfers, and Economic Efficiency: The Colorado River". The Journal of Law and Economics 23 (1): 111–134. doi:10.1086/466954. ISSN 0022-2186. https://authors.library.caltech.edu/83629/1/sswp228%20-%20published.pdf. Retrieved 2019-12-25.
- ↑ Johnson, Ronald N.; Gisser, Micha; Werner, Michael (1981). "The Definition of a Surface Water Right and Transferability". The Journal of Law and Economics 24 (2): 273–288. doi:10.1086/466984. ISSN 0022-2186.
- ↑ Anthony T. Kronman, The Lost Lawyer 166 (1993).
- ↑ Schlag, Pierre (2013-09-17). Coase Minus the Coase Theorem – Some Problems with Chicago Transaction Cost Analysis. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network.
- ↑ The law and economics of development - Edgardo Buscaglia, William Ratliff and Robert Cooter Libraries, JAI Press, 1997, ISBN 0762301074
- ↑ "Essays on Law and Economics". http://www.duncankennedy.net/topics/law_economics.html.
- ↑ Hanson, Jon D. (2012). Hanson, Jon. ed (in en-US). Ideology, Psychology, and Law. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199737512.001.0001. ISBN 9780199918638. https://www.oxfordscholarship.com/view/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199737512.001.0001/acprof-9780199737512.
- ↑ 54.0 54.1 Markovits, Richard (1998). Second-Best Theory and Law & Economics: An Introduction. 73. Chicago-Kent Law Review.
- ↑ Bayern, Shawn (2023-10-31). The Analytical Failures of Law and Economics (1 ed.). Cambridge University Press. pp. 12–24. doi:10.1017/9781009159203. ISBN 978-1-009-15920-3. https://www.cambridge.org/core/product/identifier/9781009159203/type/book.
- ↑ Leff, Arthur Allen (1974). "Economic Analysis of Law: Some Realism about Nominalism". Virginia Law Review 60 (3): 469–481. doi:10.2307/1072437. ISSN 0042-6601. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1072437.
- ↑ Cullerne Bown, William. (2022-12-23). "An epistemic theory of the criminal process, Part II: Packer, Posner and epistemic pressure" (in en). Law, Probability and Risk.. https://academic.oup.com/lpr/article-abstract/21/1/61/6958535.
- ↑ Baird, Douglas G.; Gertner, Robert H.; Picker, Randal C. (1998) (in en). Game Theory and the Law. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674341111. https://books.google.com/books?id=ncEJHu35yvQC&q=Game+theory+and+the+law&pg=PR11.
- ↑ Jolls, Christine; Sunstein, Cass R.; Thaler, Richard (1997–1998). "A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics". Stanford Law Review 50 (5): 1471. doi:10.2307/1229304. https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/stflr50&id=1489&div=&collection=.
- ↑ Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
- ↑ Alvarez, José E. (2018). "The Human Right of Property" (in en). University of Miami Law Review 72: 580. https://repository.law.miami.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4533&context=umlr.
Further reading
- Kai Purnhagen Never the Twain Shall Meet? – A Critical Perspective on Cultural Limits Between Internal Continental Dogmatism and Consequential US-Style Law and Economics Theory in Klaus Mathis Law and Economics in Europe (Springer Science), pp. 3–21, available at [1]
- Giovanni Bianco, Costituzione ed economia, Giappichelli, Torino, 1999.ISBN:978-8834892718.
- Bouckaert, Boudewijn, and Gerrit De Geest, eds. (2000). Encyclopedia of Law and Economics (Edward Elgar, Online version.
- Coase, Ronald (1990). The Firm, The Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, reprint ed.) ISBN:0-226-11101-6.
- Cooter, Robert and Thomas Ulen (2012). Law and Economics (Addison Wesley Longman, 6th edition). ISBN:0-321-33634-8
- Friedman, David (1987). "law and economics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 144–48.
- _____ (2000). Law's Order. (Princeton University Press). Chapter links. links.
- _____ (2001). Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters. ISBN:978-0691090092 .
- Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
- Georgakopoulos, Nicholas L. (2005). Principles and Methods of Law and Economics: Basic Tools for Normative Reasoning (Cambridge University Press, ISBN:0-521-82681-0).
- Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, pp. 295–360
- Kennedy, Duncan (1998). "Law-and-Economics from the Perspective of Critical Legal Studies" (from The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law PDF
- Kornhauser, Lewis (2006). "The Economic Analysis of Law," Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
- Mestmäcker, Ernst-Joachim (2007). A Legal Theory without Law: Posner v. Hayek on Economic Analysis of Law. Tübingen: Mohr. ISBN 978-3-16-149276-1.
- Mackaay, Ejan (2013), Law and Economics for Civil Law Systems, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, ISBN:978-1848443099; softcover forthcoming 2014 [2]
- Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. https://global.oup.com/ushe/product/microeconomic-theory-9780195073409?cc=us&lang=en&.
- Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Steven Shavell (2008). "law, economic analysis of," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract and pre-publication copy.
- Posner, Richard A. (2011). Economic Analysis of Law (New York, Wolters Kluwer Law & Business, 8th edition). ISBN:978-0735594425.
- _____ (2006). "A Review of Steven Shavell's Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law," Journal of Economic Literature, 44(2), pp. 405–14[yes|permanent dead link|dead link}}] (press +).
- Schäfer, Hans-Bernd and Claus Ott (2004), “Economic Analysis of Civil Law”, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing; ISBN:1843762773
- Shavell, Steven (2004). Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Harvard University Press. Description and scroll to chapter-preview links.
- Robé, Jean-Philippe The Legal Structure of the Firm, Accounting, Economics, and Law: Vol. 1 : Iss. 1, Article 5, 2011. Jean-Philippe Robé
- Viscusi, W. Kip; Vernon, John M.; Harrington Jr., Joseph E. (2005). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-28732-6. https://books.google.com/books?id=Zi03AgAAQBAJ.
- Stojanovich A., Silvestri P. (Eds.), "Special Issue: On 'The Future of Law and Economics' by Guido Calabresi: An Interdisciplinary Dialogue", Global Jurist, 19(2019), 3.
External links
- "Law and Economics" article in the Internet Encyclopedia of Philosophy
- Law & Economics LAB
- Paper describing the effects of law and economics on inequality
Original source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Law and economics.
Read more |