Auction theory

From HandWiki
Short description: Branch of applied economics regarding the behavior of bidders in auctions


Auction theory is an applied branch of economics which deals with how bidders act in auction markets and researches how the features of auction markets incentivise predictable outcomes. Auction theory is a tool used to inform the design of real-world auctions. Sellers use auction theory to raise higher revenues while allowing buyers to procure at a lower cost. The conference of the price between the buyer and seller is an economic equilibrium. Auction theorists design rules for auctions to address issues which can lead to market failure. The design of these rulesets encourages optimal bidding strategies among a variety of informational settings.[1] The 2020 Nobel Prize for Economics was awarded to Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson “for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats.”[2]

Introduction

Auctions facilitate transactions by enforcing a specific set of rules regarding the resource allocations of a group of bidders. Theorists consider auctions to be economic games that differ in two respects: format and information.[3] The format defines the rules for the announcement of prices, the placement of bids, the updating of prices, the auction close, and the way a winner is picked.[4] The way auctions differ with respect to information regards the asymmetries of information that exist between bidders.[5] In most auctions, bidders have some private information that they choose to withhold from their competitors. For example, bidders usually know their personal valuation of the item, which is unknown to the other bidders and the seller; however, the behaviour of bidders can influence the personal valuation of other bidders.

History

One of the historical events related to auctions that has been reported is a custom in Babylonia, namely when men try to make an offers to women in order to marry her.[6] The more familiar the auction system is, the more situations where auctions are conducted. There are auctions for various things, from livestock, rare and unusual items, to financial assets.

Non cooperative games have a long history beginning with Cournot's Duopoly model. 1994 Nobel Laureate for Economic Sciences, John Nash,[7] proved a general existence theorem for non-cooperative game which moves beyond simple zero-sum games. This theory was generalized by Vickrey (1961) to deal with the unobservable value of each buyer. By the early (1970s) auction theorists had begun defining equilibrium bidding conditions for single-object auctions under most realistic auction formats and information settings.[8] The state-of-the-art considers how multiple-object auctions can be performed efficiently

Auction types

There are traditionally four types of auction that are used for the allocation of a single item:

  • First-price sealed-bid auction in which bidders place their bid in a sealed envelope and simultaneously hand them to the auctioneer. The envelopes are opened and the individual with the highest bid wins, paying the amount bid. This form of auction requires strategic considerations since bidders must not only consider their valuation but other bidders' valuations and what other bidders believe other bidders' valuations are.[9] The first formal analysis of such an auction was by Vickrey [1961]. For the cases of two buyers and uniformly distributed values, he showed that the symmetric equilibrium strategy was to submit a bid equal to half of the buyer's value.
  • Second-price sealed-bid auctions (Vickrey auctions) in which bidders place their bid in a sealed envelope and simultaneously hand them to the auctioneer. The envelopes are opened and the individual with the highest bid wins, paying a price equal to the second-highest bid. The logic of this auction type is that the dominant strategy for all bidders is to bid their true valuation [10] William Vickrey was the first scholar to study second-price valuation auctions, but their use goes back in history with some evidence suggesting that Goethe sold his manuscripts to a publisher using the second-price auction format.[11] Online auctions often use an equivalent version of Vickrey's second-price auction wherein bidders provide proxy bids for items. A proxy bid is an amount an individual values some item at. The online auction house will bid up the price of the item until the proxy bid for the winner is at the top. However, the individual only has to pay one increment higher than the second-highest price, despite their own proxy valuation.[12]
  • Open ascending-bid auctions (English auctions) is the oldest and possibly most common type of auction in which participants make increasingly higher bids, each stopping bidding when they are not prepared to pay more than the current highest bid. This continues until no participant is prepared to make a higher bid; the highest bidder wins the auction at the final amount bid. Sometimes the lot is sold only if the bidding reaches a reserve price set by the seller.
  • Open descending-bid auctions (Dutch auctions) in which the price is set by the auctioneer at a level sufficiently high to deter all bidders, and is progressively lowered until a bidder is prepared to buy at the current price, winning the auction.

Most auction theory revolves around these four "basic" auction types. However, others have also received some academic study (see Auction § Types). Developments in the world and technology have also influenced the current auction system. With the existence of the internet, online auctions have become an option for people who want to participate in auctions.

  • Online auctions are efficient platforms for establishing precise prices based on supply and demand. Furthermore, it can overcome geographic boundaries. Online auction sites are used for a variety of purposes, such as online "garage sales" to companies liquidating unwanted inventory.[13] A significant difference between online auctions and traditional auctions is that bidders on the internet are unable to inspect the actual item, leading to perceived differences between imagined and real products.[14]

Auction process

There are six basic activities that complement the auction-based trading process:[15]

  • Initial buyer and seller registration is an authentication of trading parties, exchange of cryptography keys, and profile creation.
  • Setting up a particular auction event is a step in the process of describing items sold or acquired and establishing auction rules. Auction rules define the type of auction, parameters, starting date, and closing rules.
  • Scheduling and advertising is done to attract potential buyers. Items of the same category should be auctioned together to attract potential buyers. Popular auctions can be combined with less popular auctions to persuade people to attend the less popular ones.
  • Bidding step collects bids and implements bid control rules of the auction.
  • Evaluation of bids and closing the auction implements auction closing rules and notifying winners and losers.
  • Trade settlement handles payment to seller, transfer of goods, fees to agents.

The Auction Envelope Theorem

The Auction Envelope Theorem defines certain probabilities expected to arise in an auction.[16]

The benchmark model

The benchmark model for auctions, as defined by McAfee and McMillan (1987) is as follows.

  1. All of the bidders are risk-neutral.
  2. Each bidder has a private valuation for the item (almost always) independently drawn from some probability distribution.
  3. The bidders possess symmetric information.
  4. The payment is represented as a function of only the bids.

The win probability

In an auction a buyer bidding [math]\displaystyle{ B(v) }[/math] wins if the opposing bidders have lower bids.

The map from values to bids is strictly increasing, The high value buyer therefore wins.

In statistics the probability of having the "first" value is written as

[math]\displaystyle{ W=F_({\scriptstyle\text{1}}_)(v) }[/math]

With independent values and N other bidders [math]\displaystyle{ W=F(v)^N }[/math]

The auction.

A buyer's payoff is

[math]\displaystyle{ u(v,b) = w(b)(v-b)) }[/math]

Let [math]\displaystyle{ B }[/math] be the bid that maximizes the buyer's payoff.

Therefore

[math]\displaystyle{ u(v,B)\gt u(v,b)=W(b)(v-b) }[/math]

The equilibrium payoff is therefore

[math]\displaystyle{ U(v)=W(B)(v-B)) }[/math]

Necessary condition for the maximum:

[math]\displaystyle{ \partial u/\partial b=0 }[/math] when [math]\displaystyle{ b=B }[/math]

The final step is to take the total derivative of the equilibrium payoff

[math]\displaystyle{ U'(v)=W(B)+\partial u/\partial b }[/math]

The second term is zero. Therefore

[math]\displaystyle{ U'(v)=W }[/math]

Then

[math]\displaystyle{ U'(v)=W }[/math][math]\displaystyle{ =F_({\scriptstyle\text{1}}_)(v) }[/math]

Example Uniform distribution with two buyers. For the Uniform distribution the probability if having a higher value that one other buyer is [math]\displaystyle{ F(v)=v }[/math].

Then [math]\displaystyle{ U'(v)=v }[/math]

The equilibrium payoff is therefore [math]\displaystyle{ U(v)=\textstyle \int_{0}^{v} \displaystyle xdx=(1/2)v^2 }[/math].

The win probability is [math]\displaystyle{ W=F(v)=v }[/math].

[math]\displaystyle{ U(v)=W(B)(v-B)) }[/math]

Then

[math]\displaystyle{ (1/2)v^2=v(v-B(v)) }[/math].

Rearranging this expression,

[math]\displaystyle{ B(v)=(1/2)v }[/math]

With three buyers, [math]\displaystyle{ U'(v)=W }[/math][math]\displaystyle{ =F_({\scriptstyle\text{1}}_)(v)=F(v)^2=v^2 }[/math], then [math]\displaystyle{ B(v)=(2/3)v }[/math]

With [math]\displaystyle{ N+1 }[/math] buyers [math]\displaystyle{ B(v)=(N/(N+1))v }[/math]

Lebrun (1996)[17] provides a general proof that there are no asymmetric equilibria.

Optimal Auctions

Auctions from a buyer's perspective

The revelation principle is a simple but powerful insight.

In 1979 (Riley Samuelson) proved a general Revenue equivalence theorem that applies to all buyers and hence to the seller.Their primary interest was finding out which auction rule would be better for the buyers. A rule might be, for example, that all buyers pay a nonrefundable bid. (Such auctions are conducted on-line.). The equivalence theorem shows that any allocation mechanism or auction that satisfies the four main assumptions of the benchmark model will lead to the same expected revenue for the seller. (Buyer i of with value v also has the same "payoff" or "buyer surplus" across all auctions).[18]

SYMMETRIC AUCTIONS WITH CORRELATED VALUE DISTRIBUTIONS

The first paper to build a model for a broad class of models was Milgrom and Weber's (1983) paper on auctions with affiliated values.

In a recent Working Paper General Asymmetric Auctions, Riley (2022) provides a characterization of equilibrium bids for all value distributions.. Each buyer's value can be positively or negatively correlated.

The revelation principle as applied to auctions is that the marginal buyer payoff or "buyer surplus" is P(v), the probability of being the winner.

In every participant-efficient auction, the probability of winning is 1 for a high value buyer. The marginal payoff to a buyer is therefore the same in every such auction. The payoff must therefore be the same as well.

Auctions from the seller's perspective (revenue maximization)

Quite independently and soon after, (Myerson 1981)) used the revelation principle to provide a general characterization of a revenue maximizing sealed high bid auction. In the "regular" case this is a participation-efficient auction. Setting a reserve price is therefore optimal for the seller. In the "irregular" case it has since been shown that the outcome can be implemented by prohibiting bids in certain subintervals.

Relaxing each of the four main assumptions of the benchmark model yields auction formats with unique characteristics.[18]

  • Risk-averse bidders incur some kind of cost from participating in risky behaviours, which affects their valuation of a product. In sealed-bid first-price auctions, risk-averse bidders are more willing to bid more to increase their probability of winning, which, in turn, increases their expected utility. This allows sealed-bid first-price auctions to produce higher expected revenue than English and sealed-bid second-price auctions.
  • In formats with correlated values—where the bidders’ values for the item are not independent—one of the bidders perceiving their value of the item to be high makes it more likely that the other bidders will perceive their own values to be high. A notable example of this instance is the Winner’s curse, where the results of the auction convey to the winner that everyone else estimated the value of the item to be less than they did. Additionally, the linkage principle allows revenue comparisons amongst a fairly general class of auctions with interdependence between bidders' values.
  • The asymmetric model assumes that bidders are separated into two classes that draw valuations from different distributions (e.g., dealers and collectors in an antique auction).
  • In formats with royalties or incentive payments, the seller incorporates additional factors, especially those that affect the true value of the item (e.g., supply, production costs, and royalty payments), into the price function.[18]

The theory of efficient trading processes developed in a static framework relies heavily on the premise of non-repetition. For example, an auction seller-optimal design (as derived in Myerson) involves the best lowest price that exceeds both the seller's valuation and the lowest possible buyer's valuation.

Game-theoretic models

A game-theoretic auction model is a mathematical game represented by a set of players, a set of actions (strategies) available to each player, and a payoff vector corresponding to each combination of strategies. Generally, the players are the buyer(s) and the seller(s). The action set of each player is a set of bid functions or reservation prices (reserves). Each bid function maps the player's value (in the case of a buyer) or cost (in the case of a seller) to a bid price. The payoff of each player under a combination of strategies is the expected utility (or expected profit) of that player under that combination of strategies.

Game-theoretic models of auctions and strategic bidding generally fall into either of the following two categories. In a private values model, each participant (bidder) assumes that each of the competing bidders obtains a random private value from a probability distribution. In a common value model, the participants have equal valuations of the item, but they do not have perfectly accurate information about this valuation. In lieu of knowing the exact valuation of the item, each participant can assume that any other participant obtains a random signal, which can be used to estimate the true valuation, from a probability distribution common to all bidders.[19] Usually, but not always, a private values model assumes that the values are independent across bidders, whereas a common value model usually assumes that the values are independent up to the common parameters of the probability distribution.

A more general category for strategic bidding is the affiliated values model, in which the bidder's total utility depends on both their individual private signal and some unknown common value. Both the private value and common value models can be perceived as extensions of the general affiliated values model.[20]

Ex-post equilibrium in a simple auction market.

When it is necessary to make explicit assumptions about bidders' value distributions, most of the published research assumes symmetric bidders. This means that the probability distribution from which the bidders obtain their values (or signals) is identical across bidders. In a private values model which assumes independence, symmetry implies that the bidders' values are "i.i.d." – independently and identically distributed.

An important example (which does not assume independence) is Milgrom and Weber's "general symmetric model" (1982).[21][22]

Asymmetric auctions

The earliest paper on asymmetric value distributions is by Vickrey (1961). One buyer's value is uniformly distributed on [0,1]. The other buyer has a known value of 1/2. The equilibrium bid distributions and both uniform wit support [0,1/2]..

Jump-bidding;

Suppose that the buyers' values are uniformly distributed on [0,1] and [0,2] Buyer 1 has the wider support. Then both continue to bid half their values except at v=1.

The jump bid: Buyer 2 jumps from bidding 1/2 to bidding 3/4. If buyer 1 follows suit she halves her profit margin and less the doubles her win probability (because of the tie breaking rule (a coin toss)

So buyer 2 does not jump. This makes buyer 1 much better off. He wins for use if his value is above 1/2.

The next paper by Maskin and Riley (2000) provides a qualitative characterization of equilibrium bids when the "strong buyer" S has a value distribution that dominates that of the weak buyer" under the assumption of conditional stochastic dominance. (first order stochastic dominance for every right-truncated value distribution). Another early contribution is Keith Waehrer's 1999 article.[23] Later published research include Susan Athey's 2001 Econometrica article,[24] as well as Reny and Zamir (2004).[25]

Revenue equivalence

Main page: Finance:Revenue equivalence

One of the major findings of auction theory is the revenue equivalence theorem. Early equivalence results focused on a comparison of revenue in the most common auctions. The first such proof, for the case of two buyers and uniformly distributed values was by (Vickrey 1961). In 1979 (Riley Samuelson) proved a much more general result. (Quite independently and soon after, this was also derived by (Myerson 1981)).The revenue equivalence theorem states that any allocation mechanism or auction that satisfies the four main assumptions of the benchmark model will lead to the same expected revenue for the seller (and player i of type v can expect the same surplus across auction types).[18] The basic version of the theorem asserts that, as long as the SIPV (Symmetric Independent Private Value) environment assumption holds, all standard auctions give the same expected profit to the auctioneer and the same expected surplus to the bidder.[26]

Winner's curse

Main page: Social:Winner's curse

The winner's curse is a phenomenon which can occur in common value settings—when the actual values to the different bidders are unknown but correlated, and the bidders make bidding decisions based on estimated values. In such cases, the winner will tend to be the bidder with the highest estimate, but the results of the auction will show that the remaining bidders' estimates of the item's value are less than that of the winner, giving the winner the impression that they "bid too much".[18]

In an equilibrium of such a game, the winner's curse does not occur because the bidders account for the bias in their bidding strategies. Behaviorally and empirically, however, winner's curse is a common phenomenon, described in detail by Richard Thaler.

Optimal auctions

With identically and independent distributed private values, Riley and Samuelson (1981) [27] showed that in any auction or auction like action (such as the "War of Attrition") the allocation is "participant efficient", i.e. the item is allocated to a buyer submitting the highest bid with probability 1. They then showed that allocation equivalence implied payoff equivalence for all reserve prices. They then showed that discriminating against low value buyers by setting a minimum price or (reserve price) would increase expected revenue. Along with Myerson, they showed that the most profitable reserve price is independent of the number of bidders. There is a simple intuition. The reserve price only comes into play if there is a single bid. Thus it is equivalent to ask what reserve price would maximize the revenue from a single buyer. If values are uniformly distributed over the interval [0, 100], then the probability p(r) that this buyer's value is less than r is p(r) = (100-r)/100. Therefore the expected revenue is

p(r)*r = (100 - r)*r/100 =(r-50)*(r-50) + 25 .

Thus the expected revenue maximizing reserve price is 50. Myerson (1981).[28] also examined the question of whether it might ever be more profitable to design a mechanism that awards the item to a bidder other than one with the highest value. Surprisingly, this is the case. As Maskin and Riley then showed, this is equivalent to excluding bids over certain intervals above the optimal reserve price.

Bulow and Klemperer (1996) have shown that an auction with n bidders and an optimally chosen reserve price generates a smaller expected profit for the seller than a standard auction with n+1 bidders (and no reserve price).[29]

JEL classification

In the Journal of Economic Literature Classification System C7 is the classification for game theory and D44 is the classification for auctions.[30]

Applications to business strategy

Scholars of managerial economics have noted some applications of auction theory in business strategy. Namely, auction theory can be applied to preemption games and attrition games.[31]

Preemption games are a game where entrepreneurs will preempt other firms in entering a market with new technology before it's ready for commercial deployment. The value generated from waiting for the technology to become commercially viable also increases the risk that a competitor will enter the market preemptively. Preemptive games can be modeled as a first-priced sealed auction. Both companies would prefer to enter the market when the technology is ready for commercial deployment; this can be considered the valuation of both companies. However, one firm might hold information stating that technology is viable earlier than the other firm believes. The company with better information would, then, enter the market and bid to enter the market earlier, even as the risk of failure is higher.

Games of attrition are games of preempting other firms to leave the market. This often occurs in the airline industry as these markets are considered highly contestable.[32] As a new airline enters the market, they will decrease prices to gain market share. This forces the incumbent airline to also decrease prices to avoid losing market share. This creates an auction game. Usually, market entrants will use a strategy of attempting to bankrupt the incumbent. Thus, the auction is measured in how much each firm is willing to lose as they stay in the game of attrition. The firm that lasts the longest in the game wins the market share. This strategy has been used more contemporaneously by entertainment streaming services like Netflix, Hulu, Disney+ and HBOMax who are all loss-making firms attempting to gain market share by bidding on more expansive entertainment content.[33]

Auction Theory won a Nobel Prize

Two professors from Stanford University Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson successfully improved auction theory and invented several new auction formats, including Simultaneous Multiple Round Auctions (SMRA). This format combines the benefit of both English Auctions (open-outcry) and Sealed Bid auctions. SMRAs are deemed to solve the problem by Federal Communications Commission (FCC). Due to FCC wanting to sell all of its telecommunication frequency slots by using traditional auction, however, it will eventually turn out to give away the licenses for free or end up with a telecom monopoly in the United States. Eventually, simultaneous multiple round auctions have generated $20 billion in US dollars profit for the US government.[34]

The process of Simulations multiple round auctions is there had three to four round auctions. Every bidder has to seal their auction price; the auctioneer has to announce the highest price auction to every bidder every round. All the bidders can adjust and change their auction price and strategy after they listen to the highest auction price this round. The auction will maintain until the highest price of bidding price this round is lower than the last round’s highest bidding price.

SMRA is the first distinguishing feature is that this auction is going place simultaneously for different frequencies, therefore, it seriously increases the cost of speculators, by the reason sealed bidding can assure all bidding is reflecting all bidder’s valuation of price to the products. The second difference is that bidding takes place in numerous rounds and announced the highest price of bidding, hence, allowing bidders to learn more about their competitors' preferences, and information and adjust their strategy accordingly. Thus, decreasing the effect of asymmetric information inside the auction. In addition, multiple round bidding can maintain the bidder being active in the auction. It has substantially increased information for the bidder to understand the highest bidder’s price because every round after the bidding the host will announce the highest bidder's price.[35]

Footnotes

  1. The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (October 12, 2020). "Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020: Improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences.
  2. "The Prize in Economic Sciences 2020" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. October 13, 2020.
  3. The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (October 12, 2020). "Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020: Improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. pp. 1–2.
  4. The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (October 12, 2020). "Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020: Improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. p. 3.
  5. The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (October 12, 2020). "Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020: Improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. p. 3.
  6. Milgrom, Paul R. (1989). Advances in economic theory : fifth World Congress (1st pbk. ed.). Cambridge [England]: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0521389259. 
  7. Nash, John (1950). "The Bargaining Problem". Econometrica 13 (2): 155–162. doi:10.2307/1907266. https://www.eecs.harvard.edu/cs286r/courses/spring02/papers/nash50a.pdf. 
  8. The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (October 12, 2020). "Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020: Improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats" (PDF) (Press release). Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. pp. 4–5.
  9. Dixit, Avinash K.; Nalebuff, Barry J. (2008). The Art of Strategy: A Game Theorist's Guide to Success in Business and Life. New York: Norton. pp. 302–306. 
  10. Dixit, Avinash K.; Nalebuff, Barry J. (2008). The Art of Strategy: A Game Theorist's Guide to Success in Business and Life. New York: Norton. pp. 305–306. 
  11. Dixit, Avinash K.; Nalebuff, Barry J. (2008). The Art of Strategy: A Game Theorist's Guide to Success in Business and Life. New York: Norton. p. 305. 
  12. Dixit, Avinash K.; Nalebuff, Barry J. (2008). The Art of Strategy: A Game Theorist's Guide to Success in Business and Life. New York: Norton. pp. 309–310. 
  13. Ba, Sulin; Whinston, Andrew B.; Zhang, Han (1 June 2003). "Building trust in online auction markets through an economic incentive mechanism". Decision Support Systems 35 (3): 273–286. doi:10.1016/S0167-9236(02)00074-X. 
  14. Yen, Chia‐Hui; Lu, Hsi‐Peng (1 January 2008). "Factors influencing online auction repurchase intention". Internet Research 18 (1): 7–25. doi:10.1108/10662240810849568. 
  15. Kumar, Manoj; Feldman, Stuart I. (1998). "Internet Auctions". USENIX Workshop on Electronic Commerce 3: 49–60. 
  16. Riley, John G (1989-08-01). "Expected Revenue from Open and Sealed Bid Auctions". Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (3): 41–50. doi:10.1257/jep.3.3.41. ISSN 0895-3309. 
  17. Lebrun, Bernard (1996) "Existence of an equilibrium in first price auctions," Economic Theory, Vol. 7 No. 3, pp. 421–443.
  18. 18.0 18.1 18.2 18.3 18.4 McAfee, R. Preston; McMillan, John (1987). "Auctions and Bidding". Journal of Economic Literature 25 (2): 699–738. 
  19. Watson, Joel (2013). "Chapter 27: Lemons, Auctions, and Information Aggregation". Strategy: An Introduction to Game Theory, Third Edition. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Company. pp. 360–377. ISBN 978-0-393-91838-0. 
  20. Li, Tong; Perrigne, Isabelle; Vuong, Quang (2002). "Structural Estimation of the Affiliated Private Value Auction Model". The RAND Journal of Economics 33 (2): 171–193. doi:10.2307/3087429. 
  21. Milgrom, P., and R. Weber (1982) "A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding," Econometrica Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 1089–1122.
  22. Because bidders in real-world auctions are rarely symmetric, applied scientists began to research auctions with asymmetric value distributions beginning in the late 1980s. Such applied research often depended on numerical solution algorithms to compute an equilibrium and establish its properties. Preston McAfee and John McMillan (1989) simulated bidding for a government contract in which the cost distribution of domestic firms is different from the cost distribution of the foreign firms ("Government Procurement and International Trade," Journal of International Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 291–308.) One of the publications based on the earliest numerical research is Dalkir, S., J. W. Logan, and R. T. Masson, "Mergers in Symmetric and Asymmetric Noncooperative Auction Markets: The Effects on Prices and Efficiency," published in Vol. 18 of The International Journal of Industrial Organization, (2000, pp. 383–413). Other pioneering research include Tschantz, S., P. Crooke, and L. Froeb, "Mergers in Sealed versus Oral Auctions," published in Vol. 7 of The International Journal of the Economics of Business (2000, pp. 201–213).
  23. K. Waehrer (1999) "Asymmetric Auctions With Application to Joint Bidding and Mergers," International Journal of Industrial Organization 17: 437–452
  24. Athey, S. (2001) "Single Crossing Properties and the Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria in Games of Incomplete Information," Econometrica Vol. 69 No. 4, pp. 861–890.
  25. Reny, P., and S. Zamir (2004) "On the Existence of Pure Strategy Monotone Equilibria in Asymmetric First-Price Auctions," Econometrica, Vol. 72 No. 4, pp. 1105–1125.
  26. Ivanova-Stenzel, Radosveta; Salmon, Timothy C. (1 September 2008). "Revenue equivalence revisited". Games and Economic Behavior 64 (1): 171–192. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2008.01.003. https://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13376/. 
  27. Riley, John G.; Samuelson, William F. (1981). "Optimal Auctions". American Economic Review 71: 381–92. 
  28. Myerson, Roger B. (1981). "Optimal Auction Design". Mathematics of Operations Research 6 (1): 58–73. doi:10.1287/moor.6.1.58. ISSN 0364-765X. 
  29. Bulow, Jeremy; Klemperer, Paul (1996). "Auctions Versus Negotiations". The American Economic Review 86 (1): 180–194. ISSN 0002-8282. 
  30. "Journal of Economic Literature Classification System". American Economic Association. http://aea-web.org/journal/jel_class_system.html.  (D: Microeconomics, D4: Market Structure and Pricing, D44: Auctions)
  31. Dixit, Avinash K.; Nalebuff, Barry J. (2008). The Art of Strategy: A Game Theorist's Guide to Success in Business and Life. New York: Norton. pp. 322–326. ISBN 9780393062434. https://books.google.com/books?id=KKwBZ0PYPXQC. 
  32. Bailey, Elizabeth; Baumol, William (1984). "Derregulation and the Theory of Contestable Markets". Yale Journal on Regulation 1 (2): 111–137. https://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/yjreg/vol1/iss2/2/. 
  33. Aleksi, Korhonen; Janne, Rajala. Streaming Wars: Competitive Dynamics in the Online Video Streaming Industry (PDF) (Masters). Jyväskylä University School of Business and Economics.
  34. WITTE, MELISSA (19 November 2020). "The bid picture: Stanford economists explain the ideas behind their 2020 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences". https://news.stanford.edu/2020/11/19/bid-picture-nobel-prize-winners-explain-auction-theory-collaboration/. 
  35. Paul, Milgrom; Robert, Wilson (October 12, 2020). "improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats". Scientifc Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2020 (October 12, 2020). https://www.nobelprize.org/uploads/2020/09/advanced-economicsciencesprize2020.pdf. Retrieved April 26, 2022. 

Further reading

External links