Bertrand–Edgeworth model
In microeconomics, the Bertrand–Edgeworth model of price-setting oligopoly looks at what happens when there is a homogeneous product (i.e. consumers want to buy from the cheapest seller) where there is a limit to the output of firms which are willing and able to sell at a particular price. This differs from the Bertrand competition model where it is assumed that firms are willing and able to meet all demand. The limit to output can be considered as a physical capacity constraint which is the same at all prices (as in Edgeworth's work), or to vary with price under other assumptions.
History
Joseph Louis François Bertrand (1822–1900) developed the model of Bertrand competition in oligopoly. This approach was based on the assumption that there are at least two firms producing a homogenous product with constant marginal cost (this could be constant at some positive value, or with zero marginal cost as in Cournot). Consumers buy from the cheapest seller. The Bertrand–Nash equilibrium of this model is to have all (or at least two) firms setting the price equal to marginal cost. The argument is simple: if one firm sets a price above marginal cost then another firm can undercut it by a small amount (often called epsilon undercutting, where epsilon represents an arbitrarily small amount) thus the equilibrium is zero (this is sometimes called the Bertrand paradox).
The Bertrand approach assumes that firms are willing and able to supply all demand: there is no limit to the amount that they can produce or sell. Francis Ysidro Edgeworth considered the case where there is a limit to what firms can sell (a capacity constraint): he showed that if there is a fixed limit to what firms can sell, then there may exist no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium (this is sometimes called the Edgeworth paradox).[1]
Martin Shubik developed the Bertrand–Edgeworth model to allow for the firm to be willing to supply only up to its profit maximizing output at the price which it set (under profit maximization this occurs when marginal cost equals price).[2] He considered the case of strictly convex costs, where marginal cost is increasing in output. Shubik showed that if a Nash equilibrium exists, it must be the perfectly competitive price (where demand equals supply, and all firms set price equal to marginal cost). However, this can only happen if market demand is infinitely elastic (horizontal) at the competitive price. In general, as in the Edgeworth paradox, no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium will exist. Huw Dixon showed that in general a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium will exist when there are convex costs.[3] Dixon’s proof used the Existence Theorem of Partha Dasgupta and Eric Maskin.[4] Under Dixon's assumption of (weakly) convex costs, marginal cost will be non-decreasing. This is consistent with a cost function where marginal cost is flat for a range of outputs, marginal cost is smoothly increasing, or indeed where there is a kink in total cost so that marginal cost makes a discontinuous jump upwards.
There have been several responses to the non-existence of pure-strategy equilibrium identified by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth and Martin Shubik. Whilst the existence of mixed-strategy equilibrium was demonstrated by Huw Dixon, it has not proven easy to characterize what the equilibrium actually looks like. However, Allen and Hellwig[5] were able to show that in a large market with many firms, the average price set would tend to the competitive price.
It has been argued that non-pure strategies are not plausible in the context of the Bertrand–Edgworth model. Alternative approaches have included:
- Firms choose the quantity they are willing to sell up to at each price. This is a game in which price and quantity are chosen: as shown by Allen and Hellwig[6] and in a more general case by Huw Dixon[7] that the perfectly competitive price is the unique pure-strategy equilibrium.
- Firms have to meet all demand at the price they set as proposed by Krishnendu Ghosh Dastidar[8] or pay some cost for turning away customers.[9] Whilst this can ensure the existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, it comes at the cost of generating multiple equilibria. However, as shown by Huw Dixon, if the cost of turning customers away is sufficiently small, then any pure-strategy equilibria that exist will be close to the competitive equilibrium.
- Introducing product differentiation, as proposed by Jean-Pascal Benassy.[10] This is more of a synthesis of monopolistic competition with the Bertrand–Edgeworth model, but Benassy showed that if the elasticity of demand for the firms output is sufficiently high, then any pure strategy equilibrium that existed would be close to the competitive outcome.
- "Integer pricing" as explored by Huw Dixon.[11] Rather than treat price as a continuous variable, it is treated as a discrete variable. This means that firms cannot undercut each other by an arbitrarily small amount, one of the necessary ingredients giving rise to the non-existence of a pure strategy equilibrium. This can give rise to multiple pure-strategy equilibria, some of which may be distant from the competitive equilibrium price. More recently, Prabal Roy Chowdhury[12] has combined the notion of discrete pricing with the idea that firms choose prices and the quantities they want to sell at that price as in Allen–Hellwig.
- Epsilon equilibrium in the pure-strategy game.[13] In an epsilon equilibrium, each firm is within epsilon of its optimal price. If the epsilon is small, this might be seen as a plausible equilibrium, due perhaps to menu costs or bounded rationality. For a given [math]\displaystyle{ \varepsilon\gt 0 }[/math], if there are enough firms, then an epsilon-equilibrium exists (this result depends on how one models the residual demand – the demand faced by higher-priced firms given the sales of the lower-priced firms).
References
- ↑ Edgeworth, Francis (1889). "The pure theory of monopoly"., reprinted in Collected Papers relating to Political Economy. 1. Macmillan. 1925.
- ↑ Shubik, M. (1959). Strategy and Market Structure: Competition, Oligopoly, and the Theory of Games. New York: John Wiley and Sons. ISBN 9780598679451. https://books.google.com/books?id=co8rAAAAIAAJ.
- ↑ Dixon, H. D. (1984). "The existence of mixed-strategy equilibria in a price-setting oligopoly with convex costs". Economics Letters 16 (3–4): 205–12. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(84)90164-2.
- ↑ Dasgupta, P.; Maskin, E. (1986). "The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, I: Theory". Review of Economic Studies 53 (1): 1–26. doi:10.2307/2297588.
- ↑ Allen, B.; Hellwig, M. (1986). "Bertrand–Edgeworth oligopoly in large markets". Review of Economic Studies 53 (2): 175–204. doi:10.2307/2297646.
- ↑ Allen, Beth; Hellwig, Martin (May 1986). "Price-Setting Firms and the Oligopolistic Foundations of Perfect Competition". Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-Eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (American Economic Review) 76 (2): 387–392.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
- ↑ Dixon, Huw (1992). "The Perfectly competitive outcome as the equilibrium in an Edgeworthian price–quantity game". Economic Journal 102 (411): 301–309. doi:10.2307/2234515. http://huwdixon.org/publication_archive/articles/ej1992.pdf.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
- ↑ Dastidar, Krishnendu Ghosh (January 1995). "On the Existence of Pure Strategy Bertrand Equilibrium". Journal of Economic Theory (Springer) 5 (1): 19–32. doi:10.1007/bf01213642. http://ideas.repec.org/a/spr/joecth/v5y1995i1p19-32.html.
- ↑ Dixon, Huw (December 1990). "Bertrand–Edgeworth Equilibria when Firms Avoid Turning Customers Away". Journal of Industrial Economics (Wiley-Blackwell) 39 (2): 131–46. doi:10.2307/2098489.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
- ↑ Benassy, Jean-Pascal (April 1989). "Market Size and Substitutability in Imperfect Competition: A Bertrand–Edgeworth–Chamberlin Model". Review of Economic Studies (Wiley–Blackwell) 56 (2): 217–34. doi:10.2307/2297458. http://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/restud/v56y1989i2p217-34.html.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
- ↑ Dixon, Huw David (July 1993). "Integer Pricing and Bertrand–Edgeworth Oligopoly with Strictly Convex Costs: Is It Worth More Than a Penny?". Bulletin of Economic Research (Wiley–Blackwell) 45 (3): 257–68. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8586.1993.tb00570.x. http://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/buecrs/v45y1993i3p257-68.html.
- ↑ Chowdhury, P. R. (May 2008). Bertrand–Edgeworth "Equilibrium with a large number of firms". International Journal of Industrial Organization 26 (3): 746–761. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.05.009. http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/indorg/v26y2008i3p746-761.html Bertrand–Edgeworth.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
- ↑ Dixon, H. (1987). "Approximate Bertrand Equilibria in a replicated Industry". Review of Economic Studies 54 (1): 47–62. doi:10.2307/2297445. http://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/restud/v54y1987i1p47-62.html.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
Resources
Original source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand–Edgeworth model.
Read more |