Earth:Economics of climate change
The economics of climate change concerns the economic aspects of climate change; this can inform policies that governments might consider in response. A number of factors make this and the politics of climate change a difficult problem: it is a long-term, intergenerational problem;[2]:16, Figure 5-2 benefits and costs are distributed unequally both within and across countries; and both the scientific consensus and public opinion on climate change need to be taken into account.
Effects of climate change may last a long time, such as sea level rise which will not be reversed for thousands of years.[3]:SPM-21 The long time scales and uncertainty associated with global warming have led analysts to develop "scenarios" of future environmental, social and economic changes.[4] These scenarios can help governments understand the potential consequences of their decisions.
One of the responses to the uncertainties of global warming is to adopt a strategy of sequential decision making.[5] This strategy recognizes that decisions on global warming need to be made with incomplete information, and that decisions in the near term will have potentially long-term impacts. Governments may use risk management as part of their policy response to global warming.[6][7]:203 For instance, a risk-based approach can be applied to climate impacts which are difficult to quantify in economic terms,[7] e.g., the impacts of global warming on indigenous peoples.
Analysts have assessed global warming in relation to sustainable development.[8] Sustainable development considers how future generations might be affected by the actions of the current generation. In some areas, policies designed to address global warming may contribute positively towards other development objectives, for example abolishing fossil fuel subsidies would reduce air pollution and thus save lives.[9][10][11] Direct global fossil fuel subsidies reached $319 billion in 2017, and $5.2 trillion when indirect costs such as air pollution are priced in.[12] In other areas, the cost of global warming policies may divert resources away from other socially and environmentally beneficial investments (the opportunity costs of climate change policy).[9][10]
To achieve deep reductions in greenhouse gases and slow global warming, the financial system and the world's economies will have to adapt.[13][14]
Scenarios
One of the economic aspects of climate change is producing scenarios of future economic development. Future economic developments can, for example, affect how vulnerable society is to future climate change,[15] what the future impacts of climate change might be, as well as the level of future GHG emissions.[16]
Global futures scenarios and emissions scenarios
- [17] "Global futures" scenarios can be thought of as stories of possible futures. They allow for the description of factors which are difficult to quantify but are important in affecting future GHG emissions. The IPCC Third Assessment Report includes an assessment of 124 global futures scenarios.
These scenarios project a wide range of possible futures. Some are pessimistic, for example, 5 scenarios project the future breakdown of human society.[18] Others are optimistic, for example, in 5 other scenarios, future advances in technology solve most or all of humanity's problems. Most scenarios project increasing damage to the natural environment, but many scenarios also project this trend to reverse in the long-term.[19]
In the scenarios,[20] no strong patterns in the relationship between economic activity and GHG emissions were found. By itself, this is not proof of causation, and is only reflective of the scenarios that were assessed.
In the assessed scenarios, economic growth is compatible with increasing or decreasing GHG emissions.[20] In the latter case, emissions growth is mediated by increased energy efficiency, shifts to non-fossil energy sources, and/or shifts to a post-industrial (service-based) economy. However, in a study completed with several countries in 2022, a positive relationship was defined between renewable energy and economic growth. [21]Most scenarios projecting rising GHGs also project low levels of government intervention in the economy. Scenarios projecting falling GHGs generally have high levels of government intervention in the economy.[20]
In scenarios designed to project future GHG emissions, economic projections, for example changes in future income levels, will often necessarily be combined with other projections that affect emissions, for example nationalism.[22] Since these future changes are highly uncertain, one approach is that of scenario analysis.[4] In scenario analysis, scenarios are developed that are based on differing assumptions of future development patterns. An example of this are the shared socioeconomic pathways produced by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). These project a wide range of possible future emissions levels.
Some analysts have developed scenarios that project a continuation of current policies into the future. These scenarios are sometimes called "business-as-usual" scenarios.[23]:176
Experts who work on scenarios tend to prefer the term "projections" to "forecasts" or "predictions".[24] This distinction is made to emphasize the point that probabilities are not assigned to the scenarios,[24] and that future emissions depend on decisions made both now and into the future.[25]:75
Another approach is that of uncertainty analysis,[4] where analysts attempt to estimate the probability of future changes in emission levels.
Factors affecting emissions growth
Historically, growth in GHG emissions have been driven by economic development.[23]:169 One way of understanding trends in GHG emissions is to use the Kaya identity.[27] The Kaya identity breaks down emissions growth into the effects of changes in human population, economic affluence, and technology:[27][23]:177
CO2 emissions from energy ≡
GDP per person (or "per capita") is used as a measure of economic affluence, and changes in technology are described by the other two terms: (energy use / GDP) and (energy-related CO2 emissions / energy use). These two terms are often referred to as "energy intensity of GDP" and "carbon intensity of energy", respectively.[28] Note that the abbreviated term "carbon intensity" may also refer to the carbon intensity of GDP, i.e., (energy-related CO2 emissions / GDP).[28]
Reductions in the energy intensity of GDP and/or carbon intensity of energy will tend to reduce energy-related CO2 emissions.[23]:177 Increases in population and/or GDP per capita will tend to increase energy-related CO2 emissions. If, however, energy intensity of GDP or carbon intensity of energy were reduced to zero (i.e., complete decarbonization of the energy system), increases in population or GDP per capita would not lead to an increase in energy-related CO2 emissions.
The graph on the right shows changes in global energy-related CO2 emissions between 1971 and 2009. Also plotted are changes in world population, world GDP per capita, energy intensity of world GDP, and carbon intensity of world energy use. Over this time period, reductions in energy intensity of GDP and carbon intensity of energy use have been unable to offset increases in population and GDP per capita. Consequently, energy-related CO2 emissions have increased. Between 1971 and 2009, energy-related CO2 emissions grew on average by about 2.8% per year.[26] Population grew on average by about 2.1% per year and GDP per capita by 2.6% per year.[26] Energy intensity of GDP on average fell by about 1.1% per year, and carbon intensity of energy fell by about 0.2% per year.[26]
Trends and projections
Emissions
Equity and GHG emissions
In considering GHG emissions, there are a number of areas where equity is important. In common language equity means "the quality of being impartial" or "something that is fair and just".[29] One example of the relevance of equity to GHG emissions are the different ways in which emissions can be measured.[30]:92–97 These include the total annual emissions of one country, cumulative emissions measured over long time periods (sometimes measured over more than 100 years), average emissions per person in a country (per capita emissions), as well as measurements of energy intensity of GDP, carbon intensity of GDP, or carbon intensity of energy use (discussed earlier).[30] Different indicators of emissions provide different insights relevant to climate change policy, and have been an important issue in international climate change negotiations (e.g., see Kyoto Protocol).[31]
Developed countries' past contributions to climate change were in the process of economically developing to their current level of prosperity; developing countries are attempting to rise to this level, this being one cause of their increasing greenhouse gas emissions.[32] Equity is an issue in GHG emissions scenarios, and emerging markets countries, such as India and China, often would rather analyze per capita emissions instead of committing to aggregate emissions reduction because of historical contributions by the industrialized nations to the climate change crisis, under the principle of Common But Differentiated Responsibilities.[33]
Emissions projections
Concentrations and temperatures
As mentioned earlier, impacts of climate change are determined more by the concentration of GHGs in the atmosphere than annual GHG emissions.[34]
Temperature
Atmospheric GHG concentrations can be related to changes in global mean temperature by the climate sensitivity.[35]:195 Projections of future global warming are affected by different estimates of climate sensitivity.[36] For a given increase in the atmospheric concentration of GHGs, high estimates of climate sensitivity suggest that relatively more future warming will occur, while low estimates of climate sensitivity suggest that relatively less future warming will occur.[35] Lower values would correspond with less severe climate impacts, while higher values would correspond with more severe impacts.[37]
In the scientific literature, there is sometimes a focus on "best estimate" or "likely" values of climate sensitivity.[38] However, from a risk management perspective (discussed below), values outside of "likely" ranges are relevant, because, though these values are less probable, they could be associated with more severe climate impacts[37] (the statistical definition of risk = probability of an impact × magnitude of the impact).[7]:208
Analysts have also looked at how uncertainty over climate sensitivity affects economic estimates of climate change impacts.[39] Policy guidance from cost-benefit analysis (CBA) can be extremely divergent depending on the assumptions employed.[40] Hassler et al use integrated assessment modeling to examine a range of estimates and what happens at extremes.[41]
Cost–benefit analysis
Standard cost–benefit analysis (CBA)[42] (also referred to as a monetized cost–benefit framework)[43] has been applied to the problem of climate change.[44] This requires (1) the valuation of costs and benefits using willingness to pay (WTP) or willingness to accept (WTA) compensation[43][45][46][47] as a measure of value,[42] and (2) a criterion for accepting or rejecting proposals:[42]
For (1), in CBA where WTP/WTA is used, climate change impacts are aggregated into a monetary value,[43] with environmental impacts converted into consumption equivalents,[48] and risk accounted for using certainty equivalents.[48][49] Values over time are then discounted to produce their equivalent present values.[50]
The valuation of costs and benefits of climate change can be controversial[51]:936–938 because some climate change impacts are difficult to assign a value to, e.g., ecosystems and human health.[52][53] It is also impossible to know the preferences of future generations, which affects the valuation of costs and benefits.[54]:4 Another difficulty is quantifying the risks of future climate change.[55]
For (2), the standard criterion is the Kaldor-Hicks[54]:3 compensation principle.[42] According to the compensation principle, so long as those benefiting from a particular project compensate the losers, and there is still something left over, then the result is an unambiguous gain in welfare.[42] If there are no mechanisms allowing compensation to be paid, then it is necessary to assign weights to particular individuals.[42]
One of the mechanisms for compensation is impossible for this problem: mitigation might benefit future generations at the expense of current generations, but there is no way that future generations can compensate current generations for the costs of mitigation.[54]:4 On the other hand, should future generations bear most of the costs of climate change, compensation to them would not be possible.[44] Another transfer for compensation exists between regions and populations. If, for example, some countries were to benefit from reducing climate change but others lose out, there would be no guarantee that the winners would compensate the losers.[44]
Cost–benefit analysis and risk
In a cost–benefit analysis, an acceptable risk means that the benefits of a climate policy outweigh the costs of the policy.[55] The standard rule used by public and private decision makers is that a risk will be acceptable if the expected net present value is positive.[55] The expected value is the mean of the distribution of expected outcomes.[56]:25 In other words, it is the average expected outcome for a particular decision. This criterion has been justified on the basis that:
- a policy's benefits and costs have known probabilities[55]
- economic agents (people and organizations) can diversify their own risk through insurance and other markets.[55]
On the first point, probabilities for climate change are difficult to calculate.[55] Although some impacts, such as those on human health and biodiversity, are difficult to value[55] it has been estimated that 3.5 million people die prematurely each year from air pollution from fossil fuels.[57] The health benefits of meeting climate goals substantially outweigh the costs of action.[58] According to Andrew Haines at the London School of Hygiene & Tropical Medicine the health benefits of phasing out fossil fuels measured in money (estimated by economists using the value of life for each country) are substantially more than the cost of achieving the 2 degree C goal of the Paris Agreement.[59]
On the second point, it has been suggested that insurance could be bought against climate change risks.[55] Policymakers and investors are beginning to recognize the implications of climate change for the financial sector, from both physical risks (damage to property, infrastructure, and land) and transition risk due to changes in policy, technology, and consumer and market behavior. Financial institutions are becoming increasingly aware of the need to incorporate the economics of low carbon emissions into business models.[60]
Cost–benefit analysis for mitigation and adaptation
In a cost–benefit analysis, the trade offs between climate change impacts, adaptation, and mitigation are made explicit. Cost–benefit analyses of climate change are produced using integrated assessment models (IAMs), which incorporate aspects of the natural, social, and economic sciences.
In an IAM designed for cost–benefit analysis, the costs and benefits of impacts, adaptation and mitigation are converted into monetary estimates. Some view the monetization of costs and benefits as controversial (see Economic impacts of climate change#Aggregate impacts). The "optimal" levels of mitigation and adaptation are then resolved by comparing the marginal costs of action with the marginal benefits of avoided climate change damages.[61]:654 The decision over what "optimal" is depends on subjective value judgements made by the author of the study.[62]
There are many uncertainties that affect cost–benefit analysis, for example, sector- and country-specific damage functions.[61]:654 Another example is with adaptation. The options and costs for adaptation are largely unknown,[citation needed] especially in developing countries.
Results
A common finding of cost–benefit analysis is that the optimum level of emissions reduction is modest in the near-term, with more stringent abatement in the longer-term.[63]:298[64]:20[65][better source needed] This approach might lead to a warming of more than 3 °C above the pre-industrial level.[66]:8[better source needed] In most models, benefits exceed costs for stabilization of GHGs leading to warming of 2.5 °C. No models suggest that the optimal policy is to do nothing, i.e., allow "business-as-usual" emissions.
Along the efficient emission path calculated by Nordhaus and Boyer in 2000, the long-run global average temperature after 500 years increases by 6.2 °C above the 1900 level.[67] Nordhaus and Boyer stated their concern over the potentially large and uncertain impacts of such a large environmental change. The projected temperature in this IAM, like any other, is subject to scientific uncertainty (e.g., the relationship between concentrations of GHGs and global mean temperature, which is called the climate sensitivity). Projections of future atmospheric concentrations based on emission pathways are also affected by scientific uncertainties, e.g., over how carbon sinks, such as forests, will be affected by future climate change. Klein et al. (2007) concluded that there were few high quality studies in this area, and placed low confidence in the results of cost–benefit analysis.[68]
Strengths
In spite of various uncertainties or possible criticisms of cost–benefit analysis, it does have several strengths:
- It offers an internally consistent and global comprehensive analysis of impacts.[51]:955
- Sensitivity analysis allows critical assumptions in the analysis to be changed. This can identify areas where the value of information is highest and where additional research might have the highest payoffs.[69]:119
- As uncertainty is reduced, the integrated models used in producing cost–benefit analysis might become more realistic and useful.
Risk
One of the problems of climate change are the large uncertainties over the potential impacts of climate change, and the costs and benefits of actions taken in response to climate change, e.g., in reducing GHG emissions.[72]:608 Two related ways of thinking about the problem of climate change decision-making in the presence of uncertainty are iterative risk management[73][7] and sequential decision making[74]:612–614 Considerations in a risk-based approach might include, for example, the potential for low-probability, worst-case climate change impacts.[75]
An approach based on sequential decision making recognises that, over time, decisions related to climate change can be revised in the light of improved information.[5] This is particularly important with respect to climate change, due to the long-term nature of the problem. A near-term hedging strategy concerned with reducing future climate impacts might favour stringent, near-term emissions reductions.[74] As stated earlier, carbon dioxide accumulates in the atmosphere, and to stabilize the atmospheric concentration of CO
2, emissions would need to be drastically reduced from their present level (refer to diagram opposite).[70] Stringent near-term emissions reductions allow for greater future flexibility with regard to a low stabilization target, e.g., 450 parts-per-million (ppm) CO
2. To put it differently, stringent near-term emissions abatement can be seen as having an option value in allowing for lower, long-term stabilization targets. This option may be lost if near-term emissions abatement is less stringent.[76]
On the other hand, a view may be taken that points to the benefits of improved information over time. This may suggest an approach where near-term emissions abatement is more modest.[77] Another way of viewing the problem is to look at the potential irreversibility of future climate change impacts (e.g., damages to ecosystems) against the irreversibility of making investments in efforts to reduce emissions (see also Economics of climate change mitigation).[5] Overall, a range of arguments can be made in favour of policies where emissions are reduced stringently or modestly in the near-term (see: Economics of climate change mitigation).[78]:657–660
Resilient and adaptive strategies
Granger Morgan et al. (2009)[71] suggested two related decision-making management strategies that might be particularly appealing when faced with high uncertainty. The first were resilient strategies. This seeks to identify a range of possible future circumstances, and then choose approaches that work reasonably well across all the range. The second were adaptive strategies. The idea here is to choose strategies that can be improved as more is learned as the future progresses. Granger Morgan contrasted these two approaches with the cost–benefit approach, which seeks to find an optimal strategy.[71]
Portfolio theory
An example of a strategy that is based on risk is portfolio theory. This suggests that a reasonable response to uncertainty is to have a wide portfolio of possible responses. In the case of climate change, mitigation can be viewed as an effort to reduce the chance of climate change impacts.[56]:24 Adaptation acts as insurance against the chance that unfavourable impacts occur.[79] The risk associated with these impacts can also be spread.[clarification needed] As part of a policy portfolio, climate research can help when making future decisions. Technology research can help to lower future costs.
Optimal choices and risk aversion
|Economics of climate change mitigation#Decision analysis ]] and Economics of global warming#Trade offs
The optimal result of decision analysis depends on how "optimal" is defined.[80] Decision analysis requires a selection criterion to be specified. In a decision analysis based on monetized cost–benefit analysis (CBA), the optimal policy is evaluated in economic terms. The optimal result of monetized CBA maximizes net benefits. Another type of decision analysis is cost-effectiveness analysis. Cost-effectiveness analysis aims to minimize net costs.
Monetized CBA may be used to decide on the policy objective, e.g., how much emissions should be allowed to grow over time. The benefits of emissions reductions are included as part of the assessment.
Unlike monetized CBA, cost-effectiveness analysis does not suggest an optimal climate policy. For example, cost-effectiveness analysis may be used to determine how to stabilize atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations at lowest cost. However, the actual choice of stabilization target (e.g., 450 or 550 ppm carbon dioxide equivalent), is not "decided" in the analysis.
The choice of selection criterion for decision analysis is subjective.[80] The choice of criterion is made outside of the analysis (it is exogenous). One of the influences on this choice on this is attitude to risk. Risk aversion describes how willing or unwilling someone is to take risks. Evidence indicates that most, but not all, individuals[clarification needed] prefer certain outcomes to uncertain ones. Risk-averse individuals prefer decision criteria that reduce the chance of the worst possible outcome, while risk-seeking individuals prefer decision criteria that maximize the chance of the best possible outcome. In terms of returns on investment, if society as a whole is risk-averse, we might be willing to accept some investments with negative expected returns, e.g., in mitigation.[81] Such investments may help to reduce the possibility of future climate damages or the costs of adaptation.
Technological change too slow
Since 2021 the cost of new wind and solar power has generally been less than existing gas and coal-fired power:[82] both because of the rise in price of natural gas that year and the long-term trend of falling renewables prices.[83] However it is estimated that the steady growth part of the S-shaped growth curve of renewable power will not be enough on its own to meet the goal of the Paris Agreement to limit global warming to 1.5 degrees.[83] According to the World Resources İnstitute both non-economic and economic policies are needed to increase the rate of growth of renewables: for example they say some countries should invest more in upgrading power grids.[83]
Alternative views
As stated, there is considerable uncertainty over decisions regarding climate change, as well as different attitudes over how to proceed, e.g., attitudes to risk and valuation of climate change impacts. Risk management can be used to evaluate policy decisions based a range of criteria or viewpoints, and is not restricted to the results of particular type of analysis, e.g., monetized CBA.[84]:42 Some authors have focused on a disaggregated analysis of climate change impacts.[85]:23[86] "Disaggregated" refers to the choice to assess impacts in a variety of indicators or units, e.g., changes in agricultural yields and loss of biodiversity. By contrast, monetized CBA converts all impacts into a common unit (money), which is used to assess changes in social welfare.
International insurance
Traditional insurance works by transferring risk to those better able or more willing to bear risk, and also by the pooling of risk.[56]:25 Since the risks of climate change are, to some extent, correlated, this reduces the effectiveness of pooling. However, there is reason to believe that different regions will be affected differently by climate change. This suggests that pooling might be effective. Since developing countries appear to be potentially most at risk from the effects of climate change, developed countries could provide insurance against these risks.[87]
Disease, rising seas, reduced crop yields, and other harms driven by climate change will likely have a major deleterious impact on the economy by 2050 unless the world sharply reduces greenhouse gas emissions in the near term, according to a number of studies, including a study by the Carbon Disclosure Project and a study by insurance giant Swiss Re. The Swiss Re assessment found that annual output by the world economy will be reduced by $23 trillion annually, unless greenhouse gas emissions are adequately mitigated. As a consequence, according to the Swiss Re study, climate change will impact how the insurance industry prices a variety of risks.[88][89][90]
A study by David R. Easterling et al. estimated losses in the United States by storms causing insured losses over $5 million per year have grown steadily in the United States from about $100 million annually in the 1950s to $6 billion per year in the 1990s, and the annual number of catastrophes grew from 10 in the 1950s to 35 in the 1990s.”[91][needs update]
Authors have pointed to several reasons why commercial insurance markets cannot adequately cover risks associated with climate change.Cite error: Closing </ref>
missing for <ref>
tag:653 Adaptation activities mainly benefit those who implement them, while mitigation benefits others who may not have made mitigation investments. Mitigation can therefore be viewed as a global public good, while adaptation is either a private good in the case of autonomous adaptation, or a national or regional public good in the case of public sector policies. Climate change mitigation consist of human actions to reduce greenhouse gas emissions or to enhance carbon sinks that absorb greenhouse gases from the atmosphere.[92]:2239
Cost estimates for mitigation
Paying for an international public good
Economists generally agree on the following two principles:[56]:29
- For the purposes of analysis, it is possible to separate equity from efficiency. This implies that all emitters, regardless of whether they are rich or poor, should pay the full social costs of their actions. From this perspective, corrective (Pigouvian) taxes should be applied uniformly (see carbon tax#Economic theory). It has been suggested that countries over the average per person emissions be carbon taxed and the funds raised given to countries under the average.[93]
- It is inappropriate to redress all equity issues through climate change policies. However, climate change itself should not aggravate existing inequalities between different regions.
Some early studies suggested that a uniform carbon tax would be a fair and efficient way of reducing emissions.[94]:103–104 A carbon tax is a Pigouvian tax, and taxes fuels based on their carbon content.[95]:92 A literature assessment by Banuri et al.[94]:103–104 summarized criticisms of such a system:
- A carbon tax would impose different burdens on countries due to existing differences in tax structures, resource endowments, and development.[94]
- Most observers[96] argue that such a tax would not be fair because of differences in historical emissions and current wealth.
- A uniform carbon tax would not be Pareto efficient unless lump sum transfers were made between countries.[94] Pareto efficiency requires that the carbon tax would not make any countries worse off than they would be without the tax[97]:445[98]:72 Also, at least one country would need to be better off.[clarification needed]
An alternative approach to having a Pigouvian tax is one based on property rights. A practical example of this would be a system of emissions trading, which is essentially a privatization[clarification needed] of the atmosphere.[99] The idea of using property rights in response to an externality was put forward by Ronald Coase in The Problem of Social Cost (1960). Coase's model of social cost assumes a situation of equal bargaining power among participants and equal costs of making the bargain.[61]:668 Assigning property rights can be an efficient solution.[clarification needed] This is based on the assumption that there are no bargaining/transaction costs involved in buying or selling these property rights, and that buyers and sellers have perfect information available when making their decisions.
If these assumptions are correct, efficiency is achieved regardless of how property rights are allocated. In the case of emissions trading, this suggests that equity and efficiency can be addressed separately: equity is taken care of in the allocation of emission permits, and efficiency is promoted by the market system. In reality, however, markets do not live up to the ideal conditions that are assumed in Coase's model, with the result that there may be trade-offs between efficiency and equity.[100]
Efficiency and equity
No consensus exists on who should bear the burden of adaptation and mitigation costs.[56]:29 Several different arguments have been made over how to spread the costs and benefits of taxes or systems based on emissions trading.
One approach considers the problem from the perspective of who benefits most from the public good. This approach is sensitive to the fact that different preferences exist between different income classes. The public good is viewed in a similar way as a private good, where those who use the public good must pay for it. Some people will benefit more from the public good than others, thus creating inequalities in the absence of benefit taxes. A difficulty with public goods is determining who exactly benefits from the public good, although some estimates of the distribution of the costs and benefits of global warming have been made – see above. Additionally, this approach does not provide guidance as to how the surplus of benefits from climate policy should be shared.
A second approach has been suggested based on economics and the social welfare function. To calculate the social welfare function requires an aggregation of the impacts of climate change policies and climate change itself across all affected individuals. This calculation involves a number of complexities and controversial equity issues.[45]:460 For example, the monetization of certain impacts on human health. There is also controversy over the issue of benefits affecting one individual offsetting negative impacts on another.[51] :958 These issues to do with equity and aggregation cannot be fully resolved by economics.[94]:87
On a utilitarian basis, which has traditionally been used in welfare economics, an argument can be made for richer countries taking on most of the burdens of mitigation.[101] However, another result is possible with a different modeling of impacts. If an approach is taken where the interests of poorer people have lower weighting, the result is that there is a much weaker argument in favour of mitigation action in rich countries. Valuing climate change impacts in poorer countries less than domestic climate change impacts (both in terms of policy and the impacts of climate change) would be consistent with observed spending in rich countries on foreign aid[102][103]:229
In terms of the social welfare function, the different results depend on the elasticity of marginal utility. A declining marginal utility of consumption means that a poor person is judged to benefit more from increases in consumption relative to a richer person. A constant marginal utility of consumption does not make this distinction, and leads to the result that richer countries should mitigate less.[clarification needed]
A third approach looks at the problem from the perspective of who has contributed most to the problem. Because the industrialized countries have contributed more than two-thirds of the stock of human-induced GHGs in the atmosphere, this approach suggests that they should bear the largest share of the costs. This stock of emissions has been described as an "environmental debt".[34]:167 In terms of efficiency, this view is not supported. This is because efficiency requires incentives to be forward-looking, and not retrospective.[56]:29 The question of historical responsibility is a matter of ethics. Munasinghe et al. suggested that developed countries could address the issue by making side-payments to developing countries.[34]:167
Trade offs
It is often argued in the literature that there is a trade-off between adaptation and mitigation, in that the resources committed to one are not available for the other.[104]:94[better source needed] This is debatable in practice because the people who bear emission reduction costs or benefits are often different from those who pay or benefit from adaptation measures.
There is also a trade off in how much damage from climate change should be avoided. The assumption that it is always possible to trade off different outcomes is viewed as problematic by many people.[105]
Some of the literature has pointed to difficulties in these kinds of assumptions. For instance, there may be aversion at any price towards losing particular species.[106] This is related to climate change, since the possibility of future abrupt changes in the climate or the Earth system cannot be ruled out. For example, if the West Antarctic ice sheet was to disintegrate, it could result in a sea level rise of 4–6 meters over several centuries.
See also
- Business action on climate change
- Carbon credit
- Carbon fee and dividend
- Carbon finance
- Carbon tax
- Climate justice
- Climate lawsuit
- Degrowth
- Ecological economics
- Eco-tariff
- Emissions trading
- Energy system modeling
- Energy transition
- Environmental economics
- Environmental tax
- Green economy
- Green growth
- Green New Deal
- Just transition
- Post-growth
- Renewable resource
- Sustainable finance
References
- ↑ UNEP (1 December 2020). "Figure ES.8. Per capita and absolute CO 2 consumption emissions by four global income groups for 2015. In (book chapter) Executive Summary" (in en). Emissions Gap Report 2020. United Nations Environment Programme. p. xxv. https://www.unep.org/emissions-gap-report-2020. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ IPCC (2001), Watson, R. T.; the Core Writing Team, eds., Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report, Contribution of Working Groups I, II, and III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-80770-8, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/05/SYR_TAR_full_report.pdf (pb: ISBN:0-521-01507-3
- ↑ Masson-Delmotte, V., ed (2021). Climate Change 2021: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press (In Press). https://www.ipcc.ch/report/ar6/wg1/.
- ↑ 4.0 4.1 4.2 Report 95: Uncertainty Analysis of Climate Change and Policy Response, Cambridge MA, USA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Joint Program Report Series, December 2002, pp. 3–4, http://web.mit.edu/globalchange/www/MITJPSPGC_Rpt95.pdf, retrieved 20 January 2022
- ↑ 5.0 5.1 5.2 "1.3.2 Sequential decision making. In (book chapter) 1. Introduction: Scope of the assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, p. 26 (32 of PDF)
- ↑ "Government publishes UK's Third Climate Change Risk Assessment" (in en). https://www.gov.uk/government/news/government-publishes-uks-third-climate-change-risk-assessment.
- ↑ 7.0 7.1 7.2 7.3 "Addressing Climate Change through a Risk Management Lens". Assessing the Benefits of Avoided Climate Change: Cost-Benefit Analysis and Beyond. Proceedings of Workshop on Assessing the Benefits of Avoided Climate Change, March 16–17, 2009. Arlington, Virginia, USA: Pew Center on Global Climate Change. May 2010. https://www.c2es.org/wp-content/uploads/2010/05/workshop-proceedings-assessing-benefits-avoided-climate-change.pdf. Retrieved 18 January 2022.
- ↑ "20.1 Introduction: setting the context. In (book chapter) 20: Perspectives on Climate Change and Sustainability", Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch20s20-1.html, in IPCC AR4 WG2 2007
- ↑ 9.0 9.1 "TS.5.4 Perspectives on climate change and sustainability. In (book chapter) Technical summary", Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/tssts-5-4.html, in IPCC AR4 WG2 2007
- ↑ 10.0 10.1 "12.3 Implications of mitigation choices for sustainable development goals. In (book chapter) 12. Sustainable Development and mitigation", Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch12s12-3.html, in IPCC AR4 WG3 2007
- ↑ Shindell D; Faluvegi G; Seltzer K; Shindell C (2018). "Quantified, Localized Health Benefits of Accelerated Carbon Dioxide Emissions Reductions.". Nat Clim Change 8 (4): 291–295. doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0108-y. PMID 29623109. Bibcode: 2018NatCC...8..291S.
- ↑ Watts N et al. (2019). "The 2019 report of The Lancet Countdown on health and climate change: ensuring that the health of a child born today is not defined by a changing climate.". Lancet 394 (10211): 1836–1878. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(19)32596-6. PMID 31733928. https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/entrez/eutils/elink.fcgi?dbfrom=pubmed&tool=sumsearch.org/cite&retmode=ref&cmd=prlinks&id=31733928.
- ↑ Battiston, Stefano; Monasterolo, Irene; Riahi, Keywan; van Ruijven, Bas J. (28 May 2021). "Accounting for finance is key for climate mitigation pathways". Science 372 (6545): 918–920. doi:10.1126/science.abf3877. PMID 34016742. https://www.eurekalert.org/news-releases/632420. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ Brown, Eryn (30 September 2021). "Now is the time to prepare for the economic shocks of battling climate change". Knowable Magazine. doi:10.1146/knowable-093021-1. https://knowablemagazine.org/article/food-environment/2021/cost-of-climate-change. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ "7.4 Key future impacts and vulnerabilities. In (book chapter) 7. Industry, Settlement and Society", Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch7s7-4.html, in IPCC AR4 WG2 2007
- ↑ "3.1.4 Economic growth and convergence. In (book chapter) 3. Issues related to mitigation in the long term context". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-1-4.html. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "2.4.1 The Role of Global Futures Scenarios. In (book chapter) 2. Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications". Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. p. 137.. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ "Table 2.3: Global futures scenario groups. In (book chapter) 2. Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications". Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. p. 139.. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ "2.4.3 Global Futures Scenarios: Range of Possible Futures. In (book chapter) 2. Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications". Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. p. 138.. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ 20.0 20.1 20.2 "2.4.4 Global Futures Scenarios, Greenhouse Gas Emissions, and Sustainable Development. In (book chapter) 2. Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications". Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. pp. 140–141.. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ Wang, Qiang (10 January 2022). Renewable energy and economic growth revisited: The dual roles of resource dependence and anticorruption regulation.
- ↑ Conversi, Daniele (July 2020). "The Ultimate Challenge: Nationalism and Climate Change" (in en). Nationalities Papers 48 (4): 625–636. doi:10.1017/nps.2020.18. ISSN 0090-5992. https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/nationalities-papers/article/abs/ultimate-challenge-nationalism-and-climate-change/1667FAD7F2731F536AA671C42C8E99C3.
- ↑ 23.0 23.1 23.2 23.3 "7. Projecting the Growth of Greenhouse-Gas Emissions". Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication ed.). London, UK: HM Treasury. 2006. http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Chapter_7_Projecting_the_Growth_of_Greenhouse-Gas_Emissions.pdf.
- ↑ 24.0 24.1 "2.6.1. Treatments of Uncertainties in Previous IPCC Assessments. In (book chapter) 2. Methods and Tools", Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, in IPCC TAR WG2 2001
- ↑ World energy outlook 2009. Paris: International Energy Agency. 2009. ISBN 978-92-64-06130-9. http://large.stanford.edu/courses/2013/ph241/roberts2/docs/WEO2009.pdf. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ 26.0 26.1 26.2 26.3 International Energy Agency (IEA) (2011), CO2 Emissions From Fuel Combustion: Highlights (2011 edition), Paris, France: IEA, https://www.osti.gov/etdeweb/servlets/purl/21589332, retrieved 20 January 2022
- ↑ 27.0 27.1 "3.2.1 Drivers of emissions. In (book chapter) 3: Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 10 September 2007. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-2.html#3-2-1. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ 28.0 28.1 "3.4.1 Carbon-free energy and decarbonization. In (book chapter) 3: Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 10 September 2007. pp. 219–220. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-4-1.html. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "Summary for Policymakers", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, p. 7
- ↑ 30.0 30.1 "3.3.3 Patterns of greenhouse gas emissions. In (book chapter) 3. Equity and Social Considerations", Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press, 1996, pp. 92–96, ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf, retrieved 2022-01-19
- ↑ "Conventions of climate change: constructions of danger and the dispossession of the atmosphere". Journal of Historical Geography 35 (2): 288–292. 2008. doi:10.1016/j.jhg.2008.08.008. https://www.academia.edu/3234054.
- ↑ Chitre, Sonali P. (4 April 2011). "India's Role in an International Legal Solution to the Global Climate Change Problem". SSRN 1802862.
- ↑ Chitre, Sonali P. (2016-06-22). "Climate Change & India: Paris & Beyond". SSRN 2799605.
- ↑ 34.0 34.1 34.2 "5. Applicability of Techniques of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Climate Change". Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 1996. pp. 145–178. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf.
- ↑ 35.0 35.1 "Box 8.1 Likelihood of exceeding a temperature increase at equilibrium. In (book chapter) 8. The Challenge of Stabilisation". Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication ed.). London, UK: HM Treasury. 2006. http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Chapter_8_The_Challenge_of_Stabilisation.pdf.
- ↑ "What is 'climate sensitivity'?" (in en). https://www.metoffice.gov.uk/research/climate/understanding-climate/climate-sensitivity-explained.
- ↑ 37.0 37.1 "19.4.2.2 Scenario analysis and analysis of stabilisation targets. In (book chapter) 19. Assessing Key Vulnerabilities and the Risk from Climate Change", Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch19s19-4-2-2.html, in IPCC AR4 WG2 2007, p. 801
- ↑ IPCC (2007), "Table SPM.1. In (book chapter) Summary for Policymakers", in Core Writing Team; Pachauri, R.K; Reisinger, A., Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report, Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Geneva, Switzerland: IPCC, p. 8, ISBN 978-92-9169-122-7, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4_syr_spm.pdf, retrieved 2022-01-20
- ↑ Nordhaus, William (August 2018). "Projections and Uncertainties about Climate Change in an Era of Minimal Climate Policies" (in en). American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 10 (3): 333–360. doi:10.1257/pol.20170046. ISSN 1945-7731. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/pol.20170046. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ Ekholm, Tommi (December 2018). "Climatic Cost-benefit Analysis Under Uncertainty and Learning on Climate Sensitivity and Damages". Ecological Economics 154: 99–106. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.07.024. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/327701655. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ Hassler, John; Krusell, Per; Olovsson, Conny (2019). The consequences of uncertainty: Climate sensitivity and economic sensitivity to the climate. Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series, No. 369. Sveriges Riksbank. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215447. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ 42.0 42.1 42.2 42.3 42.4 42.5 "1.3 Contribution of Economics. In (book chapter) 1. Introduction: scope of the Assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, p. 24
- ↑ 43.0 43.1 43.2 "6.1.2 The nature of damage assessment. In (book chapter) 6. The Social Costs of Climate Change: Greenhouse Damage and the Benefits of Control", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 184–185
- ↑ 44.0 44.1 44.2 "1.4.1 General issues. In (book chapter) 1. Introduction: scope of the Assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 31–32
- ↑ 45.0 45.1 "7. Costing Methodologies.". Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 2001. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/WGIII_TAR_full_report.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-10.
- ↑ "2.5.3 Nonmarket impacts. In (book chapter) 2. Methods and Tools", IPCC TAR WG2 2001
- ↑ "2.7.2.2 Cost-Benefit Analysis. In (book chapter) 2. Methods and Tools", IPCC TAR WG2 2001
- ↑ 48.0 48.1 "4.1.1 Areas of agreement and disagreement. In (book chapter) 4. Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 130–131
- ↑ "2.5.4.1. Insurance and the Cost of Uncertainty. In (book chapter) 2. Methods and Tools", IPCC TAR WG2 2001
- ↑ "2.5.1.3 Discounting the future. In (book chapter) 2. Methods and Tools", IPCC TAR WG2 2001
- ↑ 51.0 51.1 51.2 "19. Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis". Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2001. pp. 913–970. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/wg2TARchap19.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ Ackerman, Frank; DeCanio, Stephen J.; Howarth, Richard B.; Sheeran, Kristen (August 2009). "Limitations of integrated assessment models of climate change". Climatic Change 95 (3–4): 297–315. doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9570-x. Bibcode: 2009ClCh...95..297A. https://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1007/s10584-009-9570-x.pdf. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ "The economics of avoiding action on climate change". Adbusters #75 16 (1): 4–5. 2008. https://www.clivespash.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/04/2008_Spash_Adbusters_finalcopy.pdf. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ 54.0 54.1 54.2 DeCanio, S. J. (17 October 2007), Reflections on Climate Change, Economic Development, and Global Equity : Presented at the 2007 Leontief Prize Ceremony Tufts University Global Development and Environment Institute October 17, 2007, https://www.academia.edu/19420793
- ↑ 55.0 55.1 55.2 55.3 55.4 55.5 55.6 55.7 "2.3.3 Costs, benefits and uncertainties. In (book chapter) 2. Framing issues", IPCC AR4 WG3 2007, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch2s2-3-3.html
- ↑ 56.0 56.1 56.2 56.3 56.4 56.5 "1. Introduction: scope of the Assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996
- ↑ "Rapid global switch to renewable energy estimated to save millions of lives annually". 1 April 2019. https://www.lshtm.ac.uk/newsevents/news/2019/rapid-global-switch-renewable-energy-estimated-save-millions-lives-annually.
- ↑ COP24 special report: health and climate change. World Health Organization. 2018. p. 52. ISBN 978-92-4-151497-2. https://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/handle/10665/276405/9789241514972-eng.pdf.
- ↑ "Letters to the editor". The Economist. 2019-05-09. ISSN 0013-0613. https://www.economist.com/letters/2019/05/11/letters-to-the-editor.
- ↑ Grippa, Pierpaolo; Schmittmann, Jochen; Suntheim, Felix (2019). "Climate Change and Financial Risk Central banks and financial regulators are starting to factor in climate change". Finance & Development 56 (4). https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2019/12/climate-change-central-banks-and-financial-risk-grippa.htm. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
- ↑ 61.0 61.1 61.2 Cite error: Invalid
<ref>
tag; no text was provided for refs namedtoth
- ↑ Azar, C. (1998). "Are Optimal CO2 Emissions Really Optimal? Four Critical Issues for Economists in the Greenhouse". Environmental and Resource Economics 11 (3–4): 301–315. doi:10.1023/A:1008235326513. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/azar_1998_four_crucial_issues.pdf. Retrieved 2009-01-10.
- ↑ "13. Towards a Goal for Climate-Change Policy". Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication ed.). London, UK: HM Treasury. 2006. https://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/ukgwa/20100407175526mp_/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/Chapter_13_Towards_a_Goal_for_Climate-Change_Policy.pdf.
- ↑ Heal, Geoffrey (1 January 2009). "Climate Economics: A Meta-Review and Some Suggestions for Future Research". Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 3 (1): 4–21. doi:10.1093/reep/ren014. https://sipa.columbia.edu/sites/default/files/migrated/documents/Rev%20Environ%20Econ%20Policy-2009-Heal-4-21.pdf. Retrieved 19 January 2022.
- ↑ Barker, T. (August 2008). "The economics of avoiding dangerous climate change. An editorial essay on The Stern Review". Climatic Change 89 (3–4): 173–194. doi:10.1007/s10584-008-9433-x. Bibcode: 2008ClCh...89..173B.
- ↑ The World Bank (2010). "Overview: Changing the Climate for Development". World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change. Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. pp. 8–35. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/4387/9780821379875_overview.pdf?sequence=102&isAllowed=y. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "3.5.3.3 Cost-benefit analysis, damage cost estimates and social costs of carbon. In (book chapter) 3. Issues related to mitigation in the long term context". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-5-3-3.html. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "18.4.2 Consideration of costs and damages avoided and/or benefits gained. In (book chapter): 18. Inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation.". Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch18s18-4-2.html.
- ↑ "2. Methods and Tools". Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2001. pp. 105–144. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/wg2TARchap2.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ 70.0 70.1 "BOX NT.1 Summary of Climate Change Basics. In (book chapter) Non-Technical Summary". Best Practice Approaches for Characterizing, Communicating, and Incorporating Scientific Uncertainty in Climate Decision Making.. Washington, D.C., USA: National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. January 2009. pp. 10–11. http://downloads.globalchange.gov/sap/sap5-2/sap5-2-final-report-all.pdf.
- ↑ 71.0 71.1 71.2 "7. Making Decisions in the Face of Uncertainty". Best Practice Approaches for Characterizing, Communicating, and Incorporating Scientific Uncertainty in Climate Decision Making.. Washington, D.C., USA: National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. January 2009. p. 59. http://downloads.globalchange.gov/sap/sap5-2/sap5-2-final-report-all.pdf.
- ↑ "10.1.2.4 Uncertainty Is Pervasive. In (book chapter) 10. Decision-making Frameworks", Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ "3.5.1.1 An iterative risk-management framework to articulate options. In (book chapter) 3: Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context", Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press, 10 September 2007, ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-5-1-1.html, retrieved 2022-01-19
- ↑ 74.0 74.1 "10.1.4.1 Decision Making under Uncertainty. In (book chapter) 10. Decision-making Frameworks", Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ "Article 2 of the Convention and mitigation. In (book chapter) Technical Summary". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 10 September 2007. pp. 619–690. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/tssts-ts-1-3-article-2.html. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) (November 2012), "3.7 Results of later action scenarios. In (book chapter) Chapter 3: The emissions gap – an update", The Emissions Gap Report 2012: A UNEP Synthesis Report, Nairobi, Kenya: UNEP, pp. 28–29, https://arquivo.pt/wayback/20160513232928/http:/www.unep.org/pdf/2012gapreport.pdf. Report website , which includes the Appendix, and the Executive Summary in other languages.
- ↑ Defra/HM Treasury (21 June 2005), Minutes of Evidence, Annex 3, https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/5030107.htm, in House of Lords 2005, HL 12-II (evidence)
- ↑ "10.4.3 When Should the Response Be Made? Factors Influencing the Relationships between the Near-term and Long-term Mitigation Portfolio. In (book chapter) 10. Decision-making Frameworks", Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. In IPCC TAR WG3 2001
- ↑ Eriksen, Siri; Schipper, E. Lisa F.; Scoville-Simonds, Morgan; Vincent, Katharine; Adam, Hans Nicolai; Brooks, Nick; Harding, Brian; Khatri, Dil et al. (2021-05-01). "Adaptation interventions and their effect on vulnerability in developing countries: Help, hindrance or irrelevance?" (in en). World Development 141: 105383. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105383. ISSN 0305-750X. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0305750X20305118.
- ↑ 80.0 80.1 "2.3.2 Decision analysis and climate change. In (book chapter) 2. Decision-Making Frameworks for Addressing Climate Change", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 62–63 (p.65-66 of PDF)
- ↑ "1.3.1.2 Risk aversion. In (book chapter) 1. Introduction: Scope of the Assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 24–25 (p.30-31 of PDF)
- ↑ Mercure, J.-F.; Salas, P.; Vercoulen, P.; Semieniuk, G.; Lam, A.; Pollitt, H.; Holden, P. B.; Vakilifard, N. et al. (December 2021). "Reframing incentives for climate policy action" (in en). Nature Energy 6 (12): 1133–1143. doi:10.1038/s41560-021-00934-2. ISSN 2058-7546. Bibcode: 2021NatEn...6.1133M. https://www.nature.com/articles/s41560-021-00934-2.
- ↑ 83.0 83.1 83.2 Jaeger, Joel (2021-09-20). "Explaining the Exponential Growth of Renewable Energy" (in en). World Resources Institute. https://www.wri.org/insights/growth-renewable-energy-sector-explained.
- ↑ National Research Council (2011). "Chapter Four: A Framework for Making America's Climate Choices". America's climate choices. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press. ISBN 978-0-309-14585-5. http://www.nap.edu/openbook.php?record_id=12781&page=42.
- ↑ Stern, Nicholas (May 2008). "The Economics of Climate Change". American Economic Review 98 (2): 1–37. doi:10.1257/aer.98.2.1. ISSN 0002-8282. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.98.2.1. Retrieved 18 January 2022.
- ↑ "19.1.1 Purpose, scope and structure of the chapter. In (book chapter) 19: Assessing Key Vulnerabilities and the Risk from Climate Change", Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, https://archive.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch19s19-1.html, in IPCC AR4 WG2 2007, p. 782
- ↑ Herweijer, Celine; Ranger, Nicola; Ward, Robert E T (2009-07-01). "Adaptation to Climate Change: Threats and Opportunities for the Insurance Industry" (in en). The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance - Issues and Practice 34 (3): 360–380. doi:10.1057/gpp.2009.13. ISSN 1468-0440. https://doi.org/10.1057/gpp.2009.13.
- ↑ Flavelle, Christopher (22 April 2021). "Climate Change Could Cut World Economy by $23 Trillion in 2050, Insurance Giant Warns". The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/04/22/climate/climate-change-economy.html.
- ↑ "The economics of climate change" (in en). 22 April 2021. https://www.swissre.com/institute/research/topics-and-risk-dialogues/climate-and-natural-catastrophe-risk/expertise-publication-economics-of-climate-change.html.
- ↑ Cho, Renee (20 June 2019). "How Climate Change Impacts the Economy" (in en). State of the Planet (Columbia University, Columbia Climate School, Climate, Earth, Society). https://news.climate.columbia.edu/2019/06/20/climate-change-economy-impacts/.
- ↑ Easterling, David R. (2000). "Climate Extremes: Observations, Modelling and Impacts". Science 289 (5487): 2068–2074. doi:10.1126/science.289.5487.2068. PMID 11000103. Bibcode: 2000Sci...289.2068E.
- ↑ IPCC, 2021: Annex VII: Glossary [Matthews, J.B.R., V. Möller, R. van Diemen, J.S. Fuglestvedt, V. Masson-Delmotte, C. Méndez, S. Semenov, A. Reisinger (eds.)]. In Climate Change 2021: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Masson-Delmotte, V., P. Zhai, A. Pirani, S.L. Connors, C. Péan, S. Berger, N. Caud, Y. Chen, L. Goldfarb, M.I. Gomis, M. Huang, K. Leitzell, E. Lonnoy, J.B.R. Matthews, T.K. Maycock, T. Waterfield, O. Yelekçi, R. Yu, and B. Zhou (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA, pp. 2215–2256, doi:10.1017/9781009157896.022.
- ↑ Russell-Jones, Robin (7 September 2020). "Will the Cop26 climate conference be a national embarrassment for Britain?". http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2020/sep/07/cop26-climate-conference-britain-un-glasgow.
- ↑ 94.0 94.1 94.2 94.3 94.4 "3. Equity and Social Considerations". Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 1996. pp. 79–124. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ Hoeller, Peter; Wallin, Markku (1991). "Energy Prices, Taxes and Carbon Dioxide Emissions". OECD Economic Studies (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) Autumn (17). https://www.oecd.org/economy/greeneco/34258255.pdf. Retrieved 20 January 2022.
- ↑ "Equity and Social Considerations". Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 1996. p. 104. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. https://archive.org/details/climatechange1990000unse_h1m9/page/104. "Even in a scheme involving "equal burdens", most observers argue that a uniform carbon tax would not be fair because of the many differences outlined in Section 3.3 [of the IPCC report], notably differences in historical and current emissions and in current wealth and consequent priorities."
- ↑ "Who should abate carbon emissions? An international viewpoint". Economics Letters 44. Spring 1994. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(94)90119-8. http://chichilnisky.com/pdfs/papers/93.pdf. Retrieved 2010-05-29.
- ↑ "Equitable cost-benefit analysis of climate change policies". Ecological Economics 36 (1): 71–85. 2001. doi:10.1016/s0921-8009(00)00204-4. https://www.feem.it/en/publications/feem-working-papers-note-di-lavoro-series/equitable-cost-benefit-analysis-of-climate-change/. Retrieved 2022-01-20.
- ↑ Hepburn, C. (November 2007). "Carbon Trading: A Review of the Kyoto Mechanisms". Annual Review of Environment and Resources 32: 375–393. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.32.053006.141203.
- ↑ "2.6.5 Economic efficiency and eventual trade-offs with equity. In (book chapter) 2. Framing issues". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. pp. 117–168. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4-wg3-chapter2-1.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "2.6.4 Equity consequences of different policy instruments. In (book chapter) 2. Framing issues". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. pp. 117–168. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4-wg3-chapter2-1.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ Hepburn, C. (28 February 2005). "Memorandum by Dr Cameron Hepburn, St Hugh's College, University of Oxford.". The Economics of Climate Change. Second Report of 2005–2006 Volume II, HL Paper No. 12-II. House of Lords Economic Affairs Select Committee. ISBN 978-0-19-957328-8. https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/12we10.htm. Retrieved 2010-04-06.
- ↑ Helm, D. (1 November 2008). "Climate-change policy: why has so little been achieved?". Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24 (2): 211–238. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grn014. http://www.dieterhelm.co.uk/node/671. Retrieved 2010-04-06.
- ↑ "1. Overview of Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability to Climate Change". Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2001. pp. 75–104. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/wg2TARchap1.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ "2.2.4 Risk of catastrophic or abrupt change. In (book chapter) 2. Framing issues". Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. 2007. pp. 117–168. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4-wg3-chapter2-1.pdf. Retrieved 2022-01-19.
- ↑ Face-off: Possible outcomes from the Kinder Morgan Federal Court of Appeal legal challenges. doi:10.1163/9789004322714_cclc_2018-0168-003. http://dx.doi.org/10.1163/9789004322714_cclc_2018-0168-003. Retrieved 2022-06-17.
Sources
- House of Lords (21 June 2005), The Economics of Climate Change, the Second Report of the 2005-2006 session (HL 12-I and HL 12-II), produced by the UK Parliament House of Lords (HOL) Economics Affairs Select Committee, London, UK: The Stationery Office, https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/1202.htm. High-resolution PDF versions: HL 12-I (report), HL 12-II (evidence).
- IPCC AR5 WG2 A (2014), Field, C.B., ed., Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II (WG2) to the Fifth Assessment Report (AR5) of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), Cambridge University Press, http://archive.ipcc.ch/report/ar5/wg2/. Archived
- IPCC SAR WG3 (1996), Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change, Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-56051-1, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf (pb: ISBN:0-521-56854-4)
- IPCC (2018). Global Warming of 1.5°C. An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate change, sustainable development, and efforts to eradicate poverty. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/sites/2/2019/07/SR15_Full_Report_Low_Res.pdf.
- IPCC TAR SYR (2001), Watson, R. T.; the Core Writing Team, eds., Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report, Contribution of Working Groups I, II, and III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-80770-0, http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/tar/vol4/english/index.htm, retrieved 2013-05-21 (pb: ISBN:0-521-01507-3).
- IPCC TAR WG2 (2001), McCarthy, J. J.; Canziani, O. F.; Leary, N. A. et al., eds., Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-80768-5, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/WGII_TAR_full_report-2.pdf, retrieved 2022-01-19 (pb: ISBN:0-521-01500-6).
- IPCC TAR WG3 (2001), Metz, B.; Davidson, O.; Swart, R. et al., eds., Climate Change 2001: Mitigation, Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-80769-2, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/WGIII_TAR_full_report.pdf, retrieved 17 January 2022 (pb: ISBN:0-521-01502-2).
- IPCC AR4 WG2 (2007), Parry, M. L.; Canziani, O. F.; Palutikof, J. P. et al., eds., Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-88010-7, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ar4_wg2_full_report.pdf (pb: ISBN:978-0-521-70597-4).
- IPCC AR4 WG3 (2007), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/ar4_wg3_full_report-1.pdf (pb: ISBN:978-0-521-70598-1).
External links
- Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Working Groups
- Climate change on the United Nations Economic and Social Development (UNESD) Division for Sustainable Development website.
- Climate change at the World Bank.
- Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy at University of Leeds and London School of Economics.
- Climate change: Tackling the climate crisis together, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
- Trade and climate change, World Trade Organization.
- Task Force on Low-Carbon Economic Prosperity, the World Economic Forum.
- Climate Shock, by Gernot Wagner and Martin Weitzman
Videos and podcasts
- "The economics of climate change". 2020 lecture by William Nordhaus, Sterling Professor of Economics at Yale University
- "From Climate Crisis to Real Prosperity". 2020 Reith lecture by Mark Carney, COP26 finance advisor